Shifting the impossible to the inevitable

A Private ARPA user manual

Ben Reinhardt

April 2021

Introduction

How can we enable more science fiction to become reality?

Looking to successful outliers from history is a good place to start. After digging into why DARPA works, I asked the follow-up question: how could you follow DARPA's narrow path in a world very different from the one that created it?

This piece is my answer. It both describes and provides a roadmap to actualize a hybrid for/nonprofit organization that leverages empowered program managers and externalized research to shepherd technology that is too researchy for a startup and too engineering-heavy for academia; taking on work that other organizations can't or won't by precisely mapping out blockers to potentially game-changing technology, creating precise hypotheses about how to mitigate them, and then coordinating programs to execute on those plans.

The proposal doesn't stand on its own β€” it needs a foundation of evidence and argument. This foundation spans many topics: from the role of value capture in technology creation to the now-defunct historical role of industrial labs, tactics for institutional longevity, and the nitty-gritty of how to fund operations and more.

No single organization can enable science fiction to become reality. Therefore, this document also serves as a user manual for others to build DARPA-riffs and other innovation organizations we cannot yet imagine.

There can be ecosystems that are better at generating progress than others, perhaps by orders of magnitude.

β€”Tyler Cowen and Patrick Collison, We Need a New Science of Progress

Take Home Messages

  1. A critical niche in the innovation ecosystem once occupied by industrial labs is unfilled.
  2. The current innovation ecosystem β€” academia, startups, and modern corporate R&D β€” do not cut it.
  3. A private organization that riffs on DARPA's model could fill this niche.
  4. Private ARPA (PARPA) will de-risk a series of hypotheses and go through three major evolutionary phases before it looks like its namesake.
  5. There are many tensions and incentive traps along the path to building any innovation organization. Describing them as precisely as possible may enable PARPA and other organizations to sail past them safely.

Master Plan

In short, PARPA's master plan is:

  1. Create and stress-test unintuitive research programs in a systematic (and therefore repeatable) way.
  2. Use that credibility to run a handful of research programs and produce results that wouldn't happen otherwise.
  3. Use that credibility to run more research programs and help them "graduate" to effective next steps.
  4. Make the entire cycle eventually-autocatalytic by plowing windfalls into an endowment.

Institutional Constraints in the Innovation Ecosystem

Different institutions enable certain sets of activities that we associate with innovation: Academia is good at generating novel ideas; startups are great at pushing high-potential products into new markets; and corporate R&D improves existing product lines. Together, these institutions comprise an "innovation ecosystem."

Every institutional structure has constraints that prevent it from engaging in certain activities well or at all. Imagine each institution occupying some area on a map of all possible activities β€” the institution is well suited to tackle the activities it covers and poorly suited to tackle activities at the edge or outside of its area. Some activities are covered by multiple institutions, but some aren't covered by any institutions. These activities are "constrained out" of happening by existing institutional structures.

The Missing Activities

DARPA, alongside golden age industrial labs like Bell Labs, DuPont Experimental Station, GE Laboratories, and others, developed many technologies at the core of the modern world β€” from transistors and plastics to lasers and antibiotics. These labs all enabled certain activities that are heavily constrained in the modern ecosystem.

What allowed golden-age research orgs to produce such transformative technology?

Most significantly, these organizations simultaneously:

  1. Promoted work on general purpose technologies before they became specialized.
  2. Enabled "targeted piddling around," especially with equipment and resources that would not otherwise be available.
  3. Fostered collaborations among diverse individuals with useful specialized knowledge.
  4. Shepherded smooth transitions of technologies between different readiness levels, combining manufacturing with research to create novelty and scale.
  5. Supported projects with extremely long or unknown time frames.

In short, they enabled simultaneous activity in all quadrants described in Donald Stoke's Pasteur's Quadrant :

Why DARPA and not Bell Labs?

Bell Labs may seem a more obvious model to imitate than DARPA, a government military research organization with a historically unique institutional structure. However, a closer look suggests that golden-age industrial labs required certain conditions that cannot be easily replicated today. The decline of corporate R&D was structural β€” it is the inevitable outcome of a shift in circumstances.

Tensions, Traps, and Other Topics

There are many fundamental tensions and incentive traps surrounding the path to building any innovation organization. Exploring them as explicitly and precisely as possible may enable PARPA and other organizations to navigate past them safely. This piece contains a multitude of hypotheses, theories, and intuition-pumps surrounding the central questions: How does the process of creating new impactful knowledge and technology work? And how can we do more of that better?

Along the way, we will discuss the relationship between innovation organizations and their money factories, the sales channel challenge for frontier technology, how mismatched Buxton Indexes can doom research impact, how to find researchers interested in working outside of existing institutions, speculative tactics for DARPA-riffs and other new innovation organizations, examples of the far-flung technologies that are unlikely to flourish within the status quo, and more.

However, if this document has three central topics, they are:

  1. How Money Works within an innovation organization dictates the range of incentives, activities, and potential outcomes.
  2. Legal Structure profoundly impacts the scope of an innovation organization's possibilities.
  3. Value Capture is the critical tightrope act of every successful innovation organization β€” research is expensive so insufficient funds equal institutional death, but value capture can kill the full potential of the work.

Institutional Design Is Navigating an Idea Maze

Navigating an "idea maze"Β is a useful analogy for a process that involves a series of hard-to-reverse decisions under uncertainty. This piece describes many potential junctures that someone building a DARPA-riff will probably face, how to think about them, and which fork to take.

Indeed, the entire process of reading the document might resemble a maze. You can follow each intellectual pathway that led to each conclusion. And, like a maze, I encourage you to chart your own course through the document, jumping to sections that seem most intriguing or controversial!

("Guided tours" are available that highlight material catered to various types of readers. Are you a builder? An observer? A scholar?)

If you prefer to view the project in its most concise format, a two-pager is available here. This has all the nuts and bolts needed to get building. However, if you're curious and want to follow each weave of "Ariadne's thread," please read on.

Who is this piece for?

This piece is intended for five types of readers. Selecting a persona will create a "guided tour" for that persona, highlighting the sections that are hopefully of most interest and value.

  1. "The builder" : You already believe in the importance of creating new innovation organizations and want to take action on that belief.
  2. "The supporter" : You want to support new innovation organizations with your social or financial capital. You might be a philanthropist, a member of a government, or a capitalist β€” an investor seeking monetary returns or the representative of an organization looking for technological returns.
  3. "The enthusiast" : You're interested in the question: How do we enable more creative science and technology in the world? But perhaps you aren't in a position to be a builder or supporter ... yet.
  4. "The scholar" : You have an academic interest in innovation and how it works. Maybe you're a historian, economist, or policy wonk.
  5. "The observer" : You're a curious person who enjoys learning about the world and encountering new ways of thinking. Perhaps you have a professional connection to the world of research and emerging technology ... or perhaps not.

If none of these categories fit, or the associated guides are insufficient, you can always chart your own adventure (This will eliminate the "guided tour" highlighting.)

Preliminaries

Purpose

This piece is a combination of three components: a specific organization's design; a broad proposal for a new organizational structure and an associated "research" agenda; and a synthesis of a gestalt of institutions, incentives, history, and theory that stabs at the questions "How does the process of creating new, impactful knowledge and technology work?" and "How can we do more of that better?"

It's traditional to separate the three roles this document is trying to play β€” analytical synthesis, broad proposal, and specific organizational design. However, in this case, they are too intimately entangled. Separating any one of them would force me to either leave glaring gaps or project an unwarranted level of certainty. The synthesis clearly drives the broad proposal as well as specific organizational hypotheses. A large part of the research agenda is inseparable from the specific organizational design itself β€” from "How does money work in a DARPA-riff?" to the hypothesis that good simulations could be the "Why now?" of a program design discipline. At the same time, one of the (admittedly grand) goals of the specific organization is to shift some of the conclusions in the synthesis; coupling the synthesis to the other parts allows us to say not just "Here is how the world is" but also "Here is how it could be."

An important goal for this piece is to argue for the existence of a new organization in the first place. Creating an organizational structure around a project prematurely can have many downsides, so the burden of proof rests heavily on the argument that you can't accomplish what you need to do without an "official" organizational structure. I will argue that there are a number of experiments that seem like they can only be done in the context of a new organization, and that they comprise some of the most interesting questions that the broad proposal wants to explore.

Calling out and exploring unavoidable tensions is one of the piece's core themes and an important role. Innovation organizations are shot through with Straits of Messinas, with Scylla waiting to snatch you if you focus too far on one side of a trade-off and Charybdis ready to suck you to your doom if tack too far the other way. As we will see, these tensions often have to do with incentives. With these tensions, the only way to avoid a messy fate is to first know the upcoming danger and then sail the narrow path between them, which will always be uncomfortable and require constant course correction. These tensions manifest even in the piece's very existence: If you think you have good ideas, you should show that by acting on them; at the same time, propagating the ideas can also be valuable if it enables other people to act on them. But acting on ideas and explaining them are often at odds! These conflicting prerogatives are especially true in this context where we need an explosion of new models, not a single organization. The piece's ultimate goal is to affect change, but the nature of the beast is such that I suspect neither generalizable knowledge nor a specific organizational design will be sufficient on its own. Normally, people end up on one end of the spectrum or another β€” either publishing a policy proposal or trying to lead by example (which doesn't even produce an artifact).

"Om nom nom" β€”Scylla and Charybdis

Finally, this piece is meant to build trust. Doing anything new requires trust, and research requires more trust than other disciplines. Many of these ideas don't have a "closed form" solution or a right answer, so the only way that I can convince you I've come to a reasonable conclusion is by walking you through the process of getting there. Hopefully, I can build that trust by showing you that I've really done my homework and walking you through the thoughts behind the actions. There are many uncomfortable truths and icky trade-offs embedded in good solutions R&D. Staring them in the eye requires trust in addition to raw logic.

Housekeeping

Links. Whenever I lean on an argument I make elsewhere in the piece, I try to use internal links that look like this (which will take you right back to this section). Don't worry about losing your place, because clicking an internal link will make a link back to the section you jumped from appear in the upper right corner. External links look like this one that actually links back to this piece. I try to use them only when it's painfully obvious what they link to, usually the name of a piece I'm referencing directly in the text.

Guided tours. This piece is long, and everybody will get more or less value from different sections. Selecting a persona in the section above will highlight the headings of some sections in the table of contents and gray out the headings of others in a "recommended path" for that persona. It won't make anything disappear. You can get rid of the highlighting by choosing Chart your own adventure.

Money notations. When I refer to historical monetary values, I've converted them into 2021 dollars, as indicated by, e.g., $(2021)1B for $1B in 2021 dollars.

Footnotes and sidenotes. This piece has both sidenotes and pop-up footnotes. Sidenotes are for external references to expand on a topic, while footnotes are for extraneous asides β€” you will lose nothing by not reading them.

Playfulness. This piece deals with a serious subject (to me, it is one of the most serious subjects). It's easy and often expected to take a grim authoritative tone to convey seriousness. Yet examples from Einstein's light beam to Feynman's plates and Shannon's unicycle suggest that playfulness not only does not get in the way of good work, it may be an ingredient. With that in mind, I've allowed myself to be a bit playful and irreverent at times, and hope that doesn't diminish the piece's seriousness in your eyes!

Institutional design is navigating an idea maze

Navigating an "idea maze" As far as I can tell, Balaji S. Srivasanan introduced the idea maze in his Stanford Startup Course ,Β and Chris Dixon made it well known on his blog . is a powerful analogy for a process that involves a series of hard-to-reverse decisions under uncertainty. Idea mazes usually show up in the context of startups and the decisions an entrepreneur navigates to create a company β€” "Should we sell to businesses or consumers? Build a web application or an iPhone app first?" And so on. Despite being associated with startups, there is nothing about the analogy of an idea maze that restricts it to a particular domain; it can also be used in engineering, research, or, in this case, building new institutional structures.

Image Credit: Balaji S. Srinivasan

Both abstract and concrete ideas are essential for talking about institutional structures; extending the analogy of the idea maze to the full myth of the Cretan Labyrinth can act as intellectual glue between the two. On the one hand, it's important to talk about why a new structure is even necessary and sweeping considerations that apply regardless of specifics. This is like looking at the maze from the outside β€” Where are its boundaries? Why does it exist? What dangers lurk within?At the same time, it's equally important to talk about gritty implementation details. These are the junctures in the maze and how you know that you've reached them. The abstract considerations are important for enabling people to come to their own conclusions, but without the details, it's easy to leave the difficult tradeoffs as frustrating "exercises for the the reader."

No, not that labyrinth.

This piece has a three-part structure that addresses increasingly concrete questions. The first question it strives to answer is: Why does the maze exist and where are its boundaries? The second question is: What is the layout of the maze? And finally: What is the specific path we will try to chart through the maze?

Why does the maze exist and where are its boundaries?

When your goal is to navigate a maze, it's easy to treat it as a fixture in the world and ignore what it looks like from the outside and its history. But mazes exist for reasons. Don't forget that King Minos had the Labyrinth built in order to contain the minotaur! Describing the boundaries of the maze in the context of institution building is about understanding the scope of what we're setting out to do and the constraints in the world that shape that scope. The history lets us know what's lurking inside to kill and eat us.

The exterior of the maze is fractal β€” every time you zoom in on it, there are more interesting details to explore. As such, it's easy to fall into the trap of focusing only on the contours of the questions "Why does this problem exist?" or just "Is there a problem?" Answering these is a worthy goal, but it is not our goal. I spend a good chunk of the piece describing the exterior of the maze and why it exists, but only insofar as I feel it's useful for hypothesizing about the maze's interior and the path through it. This approach will frustrate some of you for its lack of rigor and others for its extraneous information. Not all sections are for everybody!

What is the layout of the maze?

The interior layout of the maze corresponds to the myriad decisions facing anyone who is trying to build an organization to tackle a specific niche. The layout of the maze β€” with its junctures, turns, and dead ends β€” is impossible to know for sure before you enter it. Even then, you'll only be sure of the junctures and distances you've actually traversed, and only if you keep careful track of them. However, you can sketch possible layouts. This sort of hypothesizing is important and underdone, especially in public, in large part because there is not just one path through the maze! In addition to explaining which decisions I think are correct, I want to both encourage other adventurers to enter the maze and equip them as well as I can.

It's also just good practice to lay out your hypotheses about not just what experimental results will be but why they will happen. Abstractly describing decision points is admittedly a bit of a hedge! Even if our specific implementation fails, I hope that it doesn't stand as a condemnation of the entire model.

I'm going to spend a good chunk of the piece describing the potential junctures that someone building a DARPA-riff will probably face and how to think about them before explaining which fork I think is correct.

What is the path that we hope to chart through the maze?

Finally, there is the actual path through the maze. Any organization can only follow a single golden thread, making one specific design decision at each juncture. I'll lay out which choices I think are correct given the picture of the maze I've constructed. This is the most concrete part, and also the most likely to be wrong or need to change. It has been nerve-racking to write for two reasons. First, concretely stating "I think doing this will work" opens you up to the terrifying possibility of being provably wrong. When you make general statements about the world, you can always point to qualifiers about why an example does not count as a disproof. Not so when you say, "I am going to try to do X and expect Y to happen." The second reason that laying out a specific path is nerve-racking is because people tend to evaluate ideas on their most concrete manifestations. So, in the same way that people accept entire ideologies on a few compelling anecdotes, they are likely to reject the entire path, or possibly the entire argument I've laid out, based on one dumb choice.

For some readers, this will be the most interesting part β€” concrete, actionable plans. For others, this will be the most boring.

Different disciplines usually focus on one part of the maze at a time. Historical and economic work usually focuses only on why the maze exists and its boundaries. Policy proposals usually focus on the layout of the maze. Entrepreneurs usually focus on specific paths through the maze (but write about them only in retrospect). Chesterton's Fence Generally, things are done the way they are for a reason. suggests that focusing on one part at a time is probably good practice, but in this specific situation, it feels like each piece would be weak without the others. Describing the state of the world would just be adding to a growing pile of stagnation literature if it weren't supporting action. Without the context provided by the boundaries, the maze's layout would be hard to evaluate, and without the specific plan, it would feel like yet another call for someone to do something! And without the boundaries and layout, it would be impossible to evaluate a proposed path beyond "Well, that seems smart/stupid" or to have a discussion about how it could be improved from a common framework.

Part I: Problems and Possibilities - The Boundaries of the Maze and the Minotaurs Within

In this section, I want to convince you that:

  1. In the past, industrial labs filled a particular niche in the innovation ecosystem.
  2. Especially in the world of atoms, industrial labs no longer fill the niche they did in the early-to-mid 20th century.
  3. The niche industrial labs once occupied still needs to be filled, and we should not expect organizations that look like industrial labs to fill it.

Overlapping institutional constraints rule out several classes of creative work

Different institutions are each good at enabling certain sets of activities that we associate with "innovations': Academia is good at generating novel ideas; startups are great at pushing high-potential products into new markets; corporate R&D is unparalleled for improving existing product lines. Together, the institutions that play a part in creating new knowledge and technology make up an "innovation ecosystem." Both the terms "innovation" and "innovation ecosystem" are often frustrating suitcase words. But it is useful to have a shorthand for "all the institutions that enable activities that collectively cover the process of an idea becoming a new impactful idea or technology." The organizations that make up these institutions vary wildly, but they share enough commonalities that it's worth collectively referring to them as "innovation organizations.'

Obviously, each institution can't excel at every type of activity. Each institutional structure has some set of constraints that prevent it from engaging in certain activities well or at all. Many factors shape these constraints, and they are effectively synonymous with "incentives." You could think of each institution occupying some area on a map of all possible activities β€” the institution is well suited to tackle the activities it covers and poorly suited to tackle activities at the edge or outside of its area. Some activities are covered by multiple institutions, but some aren't covered by any institutions. These activities are "constrained out" of happening by existing institutional structures. For example, unsexy long-term 4 projects that won't necessarily produce a product or novel papers are simultaneously beyond the scope of venture-funded startups, corporate R&D, philanthropy, and academia. Venture-funded startups could support either a shorter timeline or more product focus; corporate R&D would want the activities to be sexy or product-focused; philanthropy would want them to be sexy; and academia would push for novelty and papers.

Of course there are counterexamples of projects with those characteristics that have been supported by existing institutional structures! It will always be possible to make arguments like "SpaceX exists, so the innovation ecosystem is fine." Antibiotics are pretty great, even though people can sometimes survive infections without them. Similarly, it's worthwhile to try to enable more constrained activities, even if a few projects make it through.

Institutionally constrained activity is a useful and precise way to think about the vibe that the world could be on a more wonderful trajectory than it's on right now. 5

Instead of arguing over The Great Stagnation See Tyler Cownen's The Great Stagnation: How America Ate All The Low-Hanging Fruit of Modern History, Got Sick, and Will (Eventually) Feel Better and a lot of related literature. or lamenting the fact that some combination of research, academia, science, and physical innovation is broken, looking through the lens of institutional constraints enables us to talk specifically about which classes of activities we expect to be happening that are missing or anemic. We can then ask what institutional constraints are creating those gaps. Instead of asking, "Where's my flying car?" See J. Storrs Hall's Where Is My Flying Car?: A Memoir of Future Past . we should be asking, "What activities would enable flying cars, and what institutional constraints are stopping them?" 8 This analysis can in turn help us address those gaps by pointing to concrete ways to adjust incentives in existing institutions or new institutions with different sets of incentives one could create. Some important questions to ask are: What incentives are preventing institutions from enabling these activities? Should I be shifting incentives within an existing institution or building a new one? How do I keep a new institution from falling into the same incentive traps?

Looking at the innovation ecosystem through this lens suggests that there are many different activities that we lump together under the umbrella of "research" or "innovation," and many ways they could be improved. There are infinitely divisible multitudes, but I will briefly note three clusters of them, primarily because they are frequently conflated and I explicitly want to say, "This piece is about one of these but not the other."

One cluster where things could be better is what I might call "breakdowns in the scientific process." Here you see issues like the replication crisis and science being judged not on one of several scientific epistemologies but on politics and its ilk. For more on breakdowns on the scientific process, I recommend Brian Nosek's work on the replication crisis or Stuart Ritchie's book Science Fictions .

Another area for improvement is in enabling paradigm-shifting work. It's a bit of a trope, but there is something in the fact that someone from 1920 would barely recognize the built world in 1970, but someone from 1970 wouldn't be too surprised by today's cars, planes, and buildings or their capabilities. The built world hasn't experienced many paradigm shifts. Similarly, physicists are still working on string theory 50 years later, and despite incredible advances in biology, nothing has displaced the structure and centrality of DNA as the dominant biological paradigm. There are legitimate arguments that this narrative ignores less visible paradigm shifts, like those in computing, or the fact that the late 19th to mid 20th century may have been a massive outlier in the realm of physical innovation. I don't think these arguments are incompatible with the assertion that we could do better.

You can roughly divide paradigm-shift-enabling activities into two distinct modes. The first mode is paradigm-shifting science. Here the sentiment is that "Einstein would be stuck in the patent office." We don't seem to have a healthy system of unfettered research that is producing paradigm shifts in how we understand the world, like those seen up through the 1950s or '60s in everything from quantum chromodynamics to general relativity and the double-helix structure of DNA. The second mode is paradigm-shifting engineering. "Where's my flying car?" We don't seem to be able to build new systems that radically change our physical capabilities. The line between science and engineering is of course nebulous, porous, and full of feedback loops.

Distinguishing between these areas isn't just a semantic exercise β€” it's important for enabling action. While they share many similarities and causal links, each area prioritizes different activities and mind-sets. As a naΓ―ve example, paradigm-shifting science probably depends on monomaniacal individuals running an idea to ground over the course of sometimes decades, while that same mode would be detrimental to paradigm-shifting engineering because it requires more pragmatism and coordination. Think Einstein and general relativity vs. Polavision, Polaroid's failed home-movie system. Polavision took 10 years and half a billion dollars to make. In Loonshots , Safi Bahcall attributes its failure to expensive but amazing features driven by Polaroid's founder. It's important to address each of these areas, but there needs to be a division of labor. Despite the temptation to do all the things, "fixing research" is going to require many new institutions (that I suspect will not scale) to address different niches in constraint space. Additionally, legible niches can help prevent mimetic infighting over who is going to "save science." Given all of this, enabling more paradigm-shifting science is incredibly important, but it won't show up in the rest of this piece as we turn our focus to the niche in the innovation ecosystem that enables paradigm-shifting engineering.

Feeling around the edges of solutions R&D

How should we think about the bundle of activities that enable paradigm-shifting engineering? The bundle is incredibly nebulous β€” absolutely real, but hard to capture, fuzzy-edged, and context-dependent. There is clearly something that is more focused on products and outcomes than the exploration of nature we associate with Newton or Einstein, yet at the same time doesn't have the steely eyed focus on commercial products we associate with Edison or Jobs. Invoking these contrasting historical figures brings to mind Donald Stokes's concept of Pasteur's Quadrant; See Pasteur's Quadrant: Basic Science and Technological Innovation . Stokes captures the mind-set excellently but doesn't focus on the actual institutional activities or how to enable them. Closer to the mark, DARPA director Arati Prabhakar captures the spirit of what we're striving for in her description of "Solutions R&D":

Solutions R&D weaves the threads of research from multiple domains together with lessons from the reality of use and practice, to demonstrate prototypes, develop tools, and build convincing evidence. Because it reaches into and connects all the parts of the innovation system, solutions R&D is a powerful way to ratchet the whole system up faster, once some initial elements of research and implementation are in place. Doing it well takes a management approach that combines a relentless focus on a bold goal with the ability to manage the high risk involved in creative experimentation. From " In the Realm of the Barely Feasible ."

"Solutions R&D" is certainly a great term for the niche we're interested in. We don't have to keep referring to it as "that bundle of activities that enables paradigm-shifting engineering" (though it would lead to an impressive word count). But like other nebulous things, such as clouds, science, and porn, a name doesn't do much to further understanding the important properties of the activities we're talking about, why they're not as common as we'd like, and how to change that.

Perhaps frustratingly, the best strategy for getting a handle on nebulous but very real things is not to rigidly define them but to "feel around the edges." People are terrible at describing what they want given a blank slate, but we're pretty good at knowing what we want when we see it. Considering what triggers the "Yes, that!" for systems R&D, we consistently arrive back at the industrial labs of the early-to-mid 20th century and Bell Labs in particular.

In the past, industrial labs filled a particular niche in the innovation ecosystem

Solutions R&D is nebulous, but we can get a sense of it by feeling around the edges and looking at what sorts of things happened at great labs that don't seem to be happening now. While industrial labs (including Bell Labs and PARC themselves) still exist, they no longer fill the niche they did in the early-to-mid 20th century . Understanding what changed and why is part of understanding the niche more broadly. While the early-to-mid 20th century was home to many well-regarded industrial labs For more about why industrial labs started, see " The Changing Structure of American Innovation : Some Cautionary Remarks for Economic Growth." , like GE Laboratories (f. 1900), DuPont Experimental Station (f. 1903), and Kodak Research Laboratories (f. 1912), Bell Labs (f. 1925) stands head and shoulders above them in the pantheon. Most of the properties and important activities in this section are drawn primarily from accounts of Bell Labs, supplemented by accounts from other labs. This Bell Labs focus is admittedly in part because of the streetlight effect β€” people have chronicled Bell Labs much more extensively β€” but also because Bell Labs" output was such an outlier. I feel comfortable doing this because, unlike the idiosyncratic success of individuals or startups, there appears to be a consistent set of activities shared across industrial labs that are missing today.

The trick here is to distinguish between the "universal" characteristics of the activities that enable good solutions R&D and the particular set of tactics and strategies that Bell Labs used to implement those characteristics. It's important to distinguish between the two because we might need to use different tactics to achieve the same characteristics in a new, 21st century context. Blindly following tactics regardless of context is ineffective and cargo-culty.

I've identified nine characteristics that enabled industrial labs to fill the solutions R&D niche .

  1. Industrial labs enabled work on general-purpose technology before it specialized.
  2. Industrial labs enabled targeted piddling around, especially with equipment and collaborators who would not otherwise be accessible.
  3. Industrial labs enabled high-collaboration research work among larger and more diverse groups of people than academia or startups.
  4. Industrial labs enabled smooth transitions of technologies between different readiness levels β€” they cared about both novelty and scale.
  5. Industrial labs provided a default customer for process improvements and default scale for products.
  6. Industrial labs often provided a precise set of problems and feedback loops about whether solutions actually solved those problems.
  7. Industrial labs provided a first-class alternative to academia in which people could still participate in the scientific enterprise.
  8. Industrial labs enabled continuous work on projects over a six-plus-year time scales. The work to create the transistor took eight years (because of a gap created by World War II) and making it mass-manufacturable took another eight.
  9. Industrial labs enabled work in Pasteur's Quadrant Pasteur's Quadrant is an excellent exploration into the nuances of different types of research. β€” explorations into natural phenomena with an eye toward exploiting those phenomena for human flourishing (and profit).

Exceptions abound, of course. Non-industrial lab organizations exist today that embody many of these characteristics, and not all golden-age industrial labs did all these things all the time. I'll expand on some (but not all) of these points below.

Industrial labs enabled work on general-purpose technology before it specialized

Specialization has a complicated relationship with new technologies. New technology will never be as good as old technology along every dimension. 15 This failure of pareto-superiority is why frontier technologies need to start in niche markets where they are especially valuable. It's rare that a technology can do well in a niche market without some specialization. If you imagine the straightest path that a technology can take to its most powerful or general use, 16 the specialization work to fit into niches can require larger or smaller diversions from this path. These diversions take the form of everything from technology development to marketing and building sales channels for a company. Going from niche to niche is essential, but you can also get stuck in a niche or jump onto a different development path altogether. Say what you will about him, but Elon Musk is the master of charting paths between niches: roadster β†’ high-end sedan β†’ mass-market car; NASA-subsidized LEO rocket β†’ GEO rocket β†’ reusable GEO rocket β†’ Starship. More time and resources can enable you to pick an "optimal" sequence of niches or search around for yet-unknown niches instead of being forced to hop into the nearest or most obvious ones. More abstractly, general purpose technology needs developmental slack. See " Studies on Slack ." In other words, if you imagine decoupling from market discipline as cave diving , industrial labs acted like extra oxygen tanks.

Industrial labs" work on unabashedly general-purpose technologies stands in contrast to modern startups. I don't know how often I've seen a presentation from a grad student or professor that goes something like, "We've invented this incredible technology that could potentially do [amazing thing]; however, it will take a lot of work to get there, so we're starting a company to build a product to do [kind of pathetic thing that will still require a lot of specialization and company-building] in [domain totally unrelated to [amazing thing]]." While I'm usually sure it's doomed to failure, it's unfortunately the best move, given history and the constraints on startups. First, many successful startups do look like they started in a tiny, scoffable niche β€” Tesla (weird rich people), NVIDIA (gamers), PayPal (Beanie Babies on eBay?), Apple (hobbyists), Twitch (life livestreaming), Amazon (books) ... the list goes on. However, each of these weird niches didn't require huge diversions from the critical path. 18 Second, "start in a niche" is folk startup wisdom for a reason . History is littered with the corpses of startups that were going to be the next platform or general-purpose technology as soon as they launched. General Magic, NeXT, Quibi, Atrium, Rethink Robotics, and Magic Leap. Many others that started with grand ambitions were forced to crawl into a niche to survive β€” I won't name names here. At the same time, startup investors want to see massive potential returns. "Find a compelling story about how a niche becomes a billion-dollar market" puts a technology between a rock and a hard place. 19

In most cases, it wouldn't have been feasible to do the necessary work to find or develop for a better niche in an academic setting either. While that work still requires "research," it also requires focus and systems engineering, both things that academia does not support for a slew of reasons .

Of course, it's possible that I and others just overestimated the potential of many of these technologies. However, the examples of technologies that were massively impactful only after "hanging out" in an industrial lab for many years would seem to argue otherwise. The transistor, public key cryptography, Pyrex, solar panels, and the graphical user interface (and personal computing in general) come to mind. Industrial labs provided the environment to do the work to get a technology to a point where it was viable for a "useful" niche, and enable it to find that niche in the first place.

In addition to giving projects longer time scales, less existential risk, and larger budgets than most startups, there are several specific ways that industrial labs helped technologies find good niches that startups and academia don't provide.

When you're still trying to figure a technology out, it's not clear which skill sets you want in the room. Industrial labs facilitated people floating between different projects loosely creating and breaking collaborations. Bell Labs was particularly good at enabling these free radicals:

"The Solar cell just sort of happened," he [Cal Fuller] said. It was not "team research" in the traditional sense, but it was made possible "because the Labs policy did not require us to get the permission of our bosses to cooperateβ€”at the Laboratories one could go directly to the person who could help." From Jon Gertner's The Idea Factory

To get the same effect at a startup, you need to either find a magical individual who has gone deep on multiple areas (an M-shaped individual instead of T-shaped individual?) or hire people who might ultimately turn out to be useless. Startups don't have the slack for this.

Another dividend from industrial labs" slack is the room to notice something unexpected, say, "Huh, that's funny," and run the anomaly to ground. Perhaps the most famous slack dividend is the discovery of the cosmic microwave background when Arno Penzias and Robert Woodrow Wilson were using the Holmdel Horn Antenna to try to do satellite communication experiments. They noticed persistent noise in their measurements that didn't seem to respond to recalibration or cleaning. Eventually, they got in touch with theorists who connected the noise they saw with predicted echoes of the (still very hypothetical) big bang. In a lower-slack (more "efficient') organization, Penzias and Wilson wouldn't have had the bandwidth to dig into the mysterious noise beyond determining that it didn't seem to be fixable.

Modern corporate R&D has become worse at enabling work on general-purpose technology. Bell Labs had a culture that was almost the polar opposite of the "demo or die" pressures in many modern organizations. The need to produce demos for corporate higher-ups may create the same pressure to specialize into a niche that makes startups bad places to develop general-purpose technology. One way to look at this would be to ask: How has the management of corporate R&D changed over time?

Industrial labs enabled targeted piddling around

It was effortless. It was easy to play with these things. It was like uncorking a bottle: Everything flowed out effortlessly. I almost tried to resist it! There was no importance to what I was doing, but ultimately there was. The diagrams and the whole business that I got the Nobel Prize for came from that piddling around with the wobbling plate.

β€”Richard Feynman, Surely You're Joking, Mr. Feynman

So many stories of golden-age industrial labs revolve around researchers literally just trying out a lot of stuff. "Hey, we came up with this new chemical, what's it useful for?" In the startup world, that's often derided as a "solution looking for a problem." Arguably, though, many important technologies started off this way β€” they weren't a hole-in-one solution to a problem. We don't seem to have a place for this "targeted piddling around" to happen anymore in situations that require specialized knowledge and equipment.

Disciplines where targeted piddling around can happen seem to be healthier. This contrast is stark looking at software compared to, say, space technology. Modern software (and slowly, biology) suggests that, in many cases, piddling around requires cheap, democratized technology. Industrial labs may have been able to loosen that requirement. Stories about DuPont and 3M's industrial labs always involve a lot of "just trying stuff out."

It's important to call attention to the "targeted" part of "targeted piddling around." Contrary to common perception, Bell Labs and PARC didn't give researchers free rein to work on whatever they wanted. There were relatively few milestones, and researchers had enough slack from management to explore adjacencies. However, people were explicitly asked to work on high-level goals that would benefit AT&T's continent-spanning communication system.

This targeting stands in contrast to accounts extolling how much freedom researchers had. It's almost impossible to confirm, but I suspect that researchers who portray themselves as having completely free rein in industrial labs are unreliable narrators. My hunch is that they felt like they had entirely free rein because the lab managers were good at hiring people whose interests were sufficiently aligned with the lab's goals that anything they chose to do was within some window. Another alternative is that they gave a few people free rein and the personal accounts are from the wunderkinds. Claude Shannon illustrates both of these possibilities β€” he was absolutely a wunderkind who was given free rein. That is, up until he started working on projects like a "mechanical mouse" that Bell Labs management couldn't possibly justify to regulators as being related to communication.

Today, many people implicitly assume that targeted piddling around happens in universities. Academics certainly do piddle around with ideas, but they're less incentivized to do it with technology applications. You can't really write a paper about how you spent a year modifying your novel technology to 100 specific applications. Even when academic labs do piddle around with technology applications, the targeting systems are often suboptimal. Often, academics are working on a specific application for a specific industrial partner, or they've effectively made up a use case out of whole cloth. This isn't to cast shade on academics, but to point out that academia is not set up to enable the sorts of feedback loops that enable just the right amount of targeting.

Getting a general-purpose technology to work is actually an iterated cycle of generality and specificity. You can think of two coupled modes: testing a general tool on many specific applications, and testing many specific components to get a general tool to work. Xerox PARC's GUI work is a good example of the former mode β€” they stress-tested the general system by using it for day-to-day work! Edison's workshop (arguably the OG industrial lab) did a lot of "trying stuff out," but the opposite way, where they had a general application in mind (lighting, recording, picking up voices on the phone) and just went through a thousand materials to see what would fit the bill.

The two modes are strongly coupled. While you're trying out a thousand things to figure out how to do a specific thing, you may realize that the five hundred and twenty-first thing is no good for the intended purpose, but might be amazing for another thing. However, that realization can easily be tossed out the door without the room to explore that hunch (because usually it's a hunch). Startups, academia, and 21st-century corporate R&D are rarely set up incentive-wise to enable running that hunch to ground. You do see this happen with software startups, because it is much easier to do targeted piddling around with software. Arguably, this could be one reason that we've seen less stagnation in software.

In contrast to many modern corporate R&D labs, Google Brain feels like it does the same thing. And perhaps that's why it feels like a much more "healthy" corporate R&D organization. In fact, a lot of the pure AI work feels a little bit like this targeted piddling around. Except that they actually don't take it the one step further to be an experimental product.

The Valley of Death is a concept that pops up repeatedly in discussions about technology development. For a good short article on the Valley of Death and its relationship to technology readiness levels, see " Technology Readiness and the Valley of Death ." It's nebulous and overloaded, but it always refers to a situation where there is secretly much more or different work than you'd expect between a development stage that feels "complete" and its natural next step; often, this is between a proof of concept and a prototype or between a prototype and a manufactured process. I don't find the concept particularly useful, but the thought that targeted piddling around might be the equivalent of "hanging out" in the Valley of Death feels generative. Hat tip to Michael Filler who (to my knowledge) created this intuition pump.

Industrial labs enabled smooth project ramp-ups with high ceilings

A common pattern in golden-age industrial labs was an individual or small team piddling around with something for a while, then roping in a few people part-time and, if it shows promise, going from there. Less than a dozen people were working on transistors at Bell Labs from 1939 to 1947, 23 but within two years, many dozens of people across multiple teams were figuring out how to manufacture them at scale and where they might fit within AT&T's system. Industrial labs were unique in their ability to enable research to start small and then ramp; smoothly transitioning along the technology readiness curve from promising experiment to prototype to end-user-quality product.

These smooth ramp-ups stand in contrast to both academic labs and startups. Projects can absolutely start small in academic labs, but they will hit a ceiling quickly because of both grant dynamics and publishing pressures. 24 Individual grants rarely break the single-digit-million dollar mark, which can only support a small team. Grants are hard to combine to fund a single project because most grants want to support a discrete piece of work. Notably, these grant dynamics mean that national labs and other non-university organizations that depend on grants are under the same constraints. If grants are the input to academic labs, publications are the output. Academic careers are built on citations, but the larger teams required by scaled-up projects either dilute citations or the work isn't novel enough to publish.

Small businesses don't have the same ceiling as academic labs, but it is hard for them to scale smoothly unless the work produces near-term profit. Unfortunately, some of the most interesting work precedes profits by a significant chunk of time (even if it will be profitable eventually). So, in order to pursue that work, a small business would need to transform itself into a high growth startup. Startups have the opposite problem of academia: They have a hard lower bound on scale. They're expected to grow quickly β€” if a startup is not constantly hiring, it's a red flag.

Ideally, the combination of academic labs and startups should enable this smooth ramping, allowing a project to pupate from academia to a startup when it's mature enough. However, there is often a gap between where you can get in an academic lab and what you need to start a startup. This is where the Valley of Death rears its head 25 again!

It's informative to compare Google Brain and (the organization-formerly-known-as-Google-)X in the context of smoothly ramping projects. Google Brain has a ton of different things being tinkered on at once, with projects of all different scales. By contrast, X famously prides itself on "killing ideas quickly." See Derek Thomson's " Google X and the Science of Radical Creativity ." The Atlantic. Hard early gating processes prevent the sort of long-burn early work that led to innovations that range from transistors to nylon; hard early gating processes are a good move for startups but perhaps squander the advantages of corporate R&D.

A quick research diversion! It would be fascinating to plot a histogram of project sizes at different organizations. My hypothesis is that the organizations that seem to be doing the best solutions R&D would have a nice, smooth decay β€” lots of little projects, and a few big projects, and many in between. I suspect that many organizations would have a hole in the middle. Maybe that's the Valley of Death appearing as a statistical phenomena.

Prototyping needs manufacturing in the room

'Manufacturing" is code for the folks who will produce the thing at scale.

It's easy to think that if the first version of an invention works consistently, you can just turn around and make a bunch of them. However, the way something is made has a huge influence on its cost. A piece of metal that a skilled craftsperson shaped by hand is much more expensive than that same piece of metal cast in a mold. Sometimes it's straightforward to turn the former into the latter. However, sometimes you need to redesign the thing almost from scratch.

The difference between these two situations is often not obvious to someone without manufacturing experience. There are many non-obvious design choices that make scaling easier or harder. For example, perfect right-angle corners in a rectangular cutout are completely free (and the default!) in a CAD model, but they are extremely hard to machine precisely. Often, you don't actually need the interior corners of the cutout to be perfect right angles, but incorporating that tolerance requires shifting other pieces of the design to accommodate it without changing functionality. These design shifts are fairly straightforward if you make them while prototyping. However, once the entire system is roughly complete, manufacturing-focused design shifts can have cascading effects that require redesigning many other components as well. This is often what's going on when there's a weirdly long gap between a company triumphantly showing off a prototype or concept version of a product and actually putting something in customers" hands.

Not only are the impediments to scaling non-obvious, they're often tacit knowledge. Instead of a legible rule of thumb like "Avoid precise angles at the bottoms of cutouts," as in the example above, someone with a lot of experience will take one look at a design and say, "Mmm, nope, that's a bad idea." It's not like they could have given you an explicit list of dos and don'ts β€” most tacit knowledge is illegible, and even if you could tease it out, the list would be infinitely long.

The importance of having manufacturing in the room applies in software as well as hardware. Different implementations of the same algorithm can parallelize fine or completely break, a functional piece of code could leave giant security holes, etc.

Healthy industrial labs require a trifecta of conditions

A pattern starts to emerge when you ask: How do golden-age industrial labs differ from corporate R&D today? Corporate R&D no longer seems to have the impressive output or cachet that it once did.

The golden-age industrial labs shared a trifecta of conditions:

  1. They were run by a monopoly.
  2. They were working on a clearly high-potential technology.
  3. That technology addressed one or more existential threats to the company. 27

Digging in:

1. They were run by a monopoly.

More specifically, they were run by companies that were extracting monopoly rents on some high-margin product. Xerox was the only game in town for copy machines (which, believe it or not, were as essential to many businesses as Excel is today), DuPont controlled well-known materials like Teflon and Lycra, Corning had Pyrex and Silicone, and of course AT&T controlled the telephone networks.

2. They were working on a clearly high-potential technology.

The technologies the labs worked on generated strong conviction that if researchers could actually pull it off technically, the parent company would be able to sell it. "If you can replace a vacuum tube with something that uses 1000x less power, of course people would use it." "If you can create glass that won't shatter when you heat it up and cool it down, of course people would use it."

What's not clear is why so many fewer technologies seem to fall under that umbrella now. It could be that we picked the low-hanging fruit in atom land. It could be that people are just more pessimistic about what we can build. It could be that timelines have shrunk, and there is no high-potential technology on those timelines. It could be that people think in terms of products instead of technology. Or it could be that companies have scoped down, so many fewer technologies fall into "things the parent company can sell."

3. That technology addressed one or more existential threats to the company.

Conditions 1 and 2 are insufficient if the technology the lab works on doesn't address existential threats to the company. This third condition is often ignored but perhaps most important! In order for an industrial lab to have the massive impact we associate with the greats, it needs active help from its parent organization to bridge the huge gap between an invention and widespread impact. Someone needs to put in active effort to diffuse technology into the world, and if the company doesn't feel intense pressure to do the diffusion work, the technology will languish.

For companies, leveraging core organizational capabilities for a new high-margin product is one of the most straightforward and common ways that new technology can address existential threats. Products become commoditized over time and companies need to keep growing to keep their valuations high. Thus, new technology can address the existential threat of low margins and flagging growth. However! If that technology isn't in line with core capabilities, taking advantage of it would require significant organizational changes, which pose a different (at least perceived) existential threat. So only technologies aligned with an organization's core capabilities address existential threats. This core-business alignment may also have contributed to industrial labs" impactfulness beyond just enabling them to exist because a technology that can take advantage of existing manufacturing and distribution channels is more likely to be impactful.

The different dynamics of Xerox PARC's work on the laser printer and the personal printer are illustrative. While PARC is legendary for the impact of its personal computing work, structurally, most of that impact shouldn't have happened. PARC's personal computing work wasn't tied to Xerox's core business. Different technologies require different organizations, and Xerox wasn't set up to scale up and build a business around personal computing. The only reason it was impactful was because of a crazy set of contingencies β€” Steve Jobs's "raiding party" and Bill Gates quickly following suit.

On the other hand, the laser printer was aligned with Xerox's core business. Xerox already sold printers and copiers; the laser printer, while a revolutionary new technology, was effectively a better version of those existing products. Xerox could leverage its management structure, manufacturing apparatus, and sales channels to diffuse laser printers with relatively few alterations.

Through the lens of aligning with core capability, Bell Labs practically cheated. AT&T's core capability was the full stack of "communications," so everything from chemistry that kept telephone poles from rotting to information theory that enabled more calls to fit into each wire was actually tied to the company's core business. Transistors had the potential to integrate directly into AT&T's system and enable faster, cheaper service. Faster, cheaper service was an existential priority for AT&T, because if it didn't continue to improve, the US government would have an excuse to break them up.

I suspect that the existential threat criterion is a big factor in the difference between Google Brain and the organization formerly known as Google X. Better machine-learning technology directly ties into Google Cloud services, search, Gmail, etc. While drone delivery and autonomous cars can potentially be big businesses, they are basically orthogonal to Google's core business.

These criteria provide a springboard to briefly explore some abstract but important concepts that seem to apply beyond industrial labs to innovation organizations more broadly.

Innovation organizations need a money factory

Innovation organizations cannot depend on their outputs for free cash flow. A core part of what makes them innovation orgs in the first place is that they create things riddled with Knightian uncertainty I'm using Knightian uncertainty in its broader sense β€” situations where there is not only uncertainty but you don't even know what the probability distribution is or even what axis to measure it on. See Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit . that aren't necessarily products. Therefore, they need a consistent external funding source, a money factory, 29 if you will. These external sources can be anything from repeated equity-based investments to a budget from a parent org to an endowment, grants, contracts, or something else.

Don't all organizations need a funding source? Well, yes. For your standard vanilla business, that funding source is just the revenue from producing a good or service and then selling it. Its cash flow is directly coupled to its output. Many organizations use financial tools to pull those cash flows from the future to the present (with some discount). These tools introduce different levels of decoupling from outputs β€” from still tightly coupled short-term loans to loosely coupled equity investments. The latter case is so decoupled from output that equity investments are a common go-to money factory.

There are two major differences between innovation orgs and other organizations that force them to decouple funding from output: They have a significantly longer cycle time and much more uncertainty about their output. Additionally, that output isn't necessarily a product that can be sold directly β€” it might be a prototype, a process improvement, or simply something that is hard to monetize without hamstringing its impact .

Historically, it takes a long time for actually new ideas to become valuable things out in the world. 30 This development time means that even if a project is going to become incredibly valuable, the organization creating it is going to be illiquid for a long time. However, the difference between innovation orgs and other businesses is not just about time scales but also about uncertainty. Large energy and infrastructure projects can take years to start making money, but the amount of money they need to get there is fairly predictable, 31 so they can theoretically get the project done with one lump of money and don't need a consistent source of cash. In addition to uncertainty about how long it will take to pay off, new types of work differ from other long-term projects because of uncertainty about whether they even will generate a return or whether seeking that return is even a good idea if their goal isn't pure profit.

The more an organization looks like past organizations, the more accurately one can predict future performance based on a set of leading indicators. By contrast, it's not clear at all what success metrics should be when you're creating something new. Unlike other long time scale organizations, an innovation organization might never converge on a set of metrics! It's almost tautological that if it is are consistently trying to create appreciably different new things then there will consistently be new ways to evaluate those things.

Despite (and in part because of) their inherent uncertainty, innovation orgs need their funding to be stable in addition to consistent. The stability may be just as important as the amount. People's incentives go haywire if they have money for now but don't know that it will continue. It might seem that a solution would be to fund individual projects instead of an organization. Unfortunately, uncertain timescales mean that it's extremely hard to do one-shot funding for any given project. 32 Innovation organizations are divas: They want consistent cash flows for inconsistent results. Through this lens, it makes sense why many rational people are hesitant to fund them in the way that they need.

An innovation org's money factory needs to deal not just with uncertain time scales and illegible leading indicators but with the fact that a chunk of the money is inevitably going to be "wasted." History shows that people are shockingly bad at predicting which research projects are going to be wildly valuable (either in the cash or impact sense) and which are going to be duds. Complicating the matter is the fact that expectations of success or failure can feed back and either hurt or help the project. 33

Just to recap: Innovation organizations need stable cash flows to support long-term projects with significant Knightian uncertainty and illegible success metrics. Despite their diversity, these common characteristics make it useful to lump funding sources for innovation orgs together into the idea of a money factory.

Innovation orgs need to be aligned with their money factories

Aligned incentives between an innovation org and its money factory is the only way an innovation org can avoid crushing oversight and have the ability to work on long-term projects. Playing the same game is the only way people can align for extremely long time scales, so if the innovation org is going to survive long term, it needs to be playing the same game as the money factory. The alignment also needs to be clear to the people who control the money and be on a time scale that's acceptable to them. While deep research into the mysteries of the universe might be in the long-term interest of the United States government, the timescale that matters to most politicians is their term in office. One of the reasons Bell Labs was able to be such an outlier is that AT&T's government-sanctioned monopoly and purview over all things communication meant that they were truly aligned with a large range of research.

The more fund-strapped the money factory is, the tighter the alignment needs to be. When AT&T, Microsoft, or Google are flush with monopoly money, they're happy to let people piddle around on whatever they wish. When stocks dip, the first programs to get cut are the ones that have the least plausible ties to the core product. Expensive research needs to address an existential threat eventually at an organizational level to maintain support. Similarly, ARPA became DARPA in 1972 because of the increased scrutiny on military spending both in the government and outside of it.

Alignment requires existential threats

What does it actually mean for an innovation org to be aligned with its money factory? When not deciding what their chaotic neutral bard will do when confronted by the town guard, people often use "alignment" as a fuzzy suitcase word. It doesn't need to be stuffed to the point of meaninglessness though β€” as a useful concept it boils down to the blunt question: Is maintaining this relationship holding off some existential threat?

It's useful to think about alignment in terms of James Carse's concept of "finite games" and "infinite games." See Finite and Infinite Games . Each person and organization is playing different games β€” whether the game is exploring the world or maximizing profits. An existential threat is something that potentially brings your game to a crashing halt. Bluntly, the only way for two entities playing different games to have the same goal is if one or both of the games would end if that shared goal wasn't met. That is, the goal addresses an existential threat. In the (grossly oversimplified) case of industrial labs and corporations, corporations are often playing the "maximize profit" game. The labs are often playing the "create sweet technology" game. In reality, the two can only be aligned if the labs" intermediate goals either directly help the corporation maximize profit or enable the corporation to keep playing its game (by deflecting antitrust litigation, for example).

Of course, "existential threat" is an extreme term that means different things for different entities. You could think of an existential threat as an event or series of events that could end something that you really do not want to end. This "threatened thing" can vary wildly in different contexts. For companies, it could be an important revenue stream or the business itself. For an individual, it could be your life or just the trajectory of your career. Clearly, what is existential is relative, and there's a continuum of importance in the threats.

While it's abstract, I find this concept useful because it allows you to roughly analyze how "aligned" two entities are and have blunt conversations about it.

Expensive research needs to address an existential threat eventually at an organizational level to maintain the support it needs to be effective

If alignment requires existential threats and innovation orgs need to be aligned with their money factories , it follows that research efforts need to address an existential risk to maintain support. I want to dig into what that means practically.

A brief aside: I'm going to focus on the realities of how innovation organizations continue to get money in the door. It's easy for the discussion to go down the track of "Painkillers vs vitamins! If I'd asked people what they wanted, they would have said "a faster horse." Make things people want! Is physics worthwhile if it never becomes a product?" And so on. These are questions of "What should a research organization do?" which is important in its own right. However, the less-discussed question is "What should a research organization do to stay alive? "

I wish this section's header could be "Research organizations 35 need to address existential threats to maintain support." The statement is both simple and bold; there are plenty of examples of research orgs that struggled with support because they didn't really address an existential threat (Dynamicland and BP Venture Research come to mind). However it's also not true: There is a large class of research organizations that maintain support but continue to limp along ineffectively (Bell Labs still exists!) So perhaps "Effective research organizations need to address existential threats" is more accurate. This would explain the difference between ARPA-E and DARPA and why Bell Labs declined once it no longer staved off regulators, among other examples.

However! There are many examples of effective research organizations that did not address existential threats. In fact, most great scientists were not actually out to address existential threats β€” Galileo, Newton, Rutherford, Einstein, etc. They just managed to cobble together enough money from patrons or side hustles to keep going. Patreon-sponsored contemporaries are similar β€” I give some money to support a few researchers, but they aren't addressing any existential threat for me. The notable pattern is that these examples are all individuals or small groups. Aha! It suggests that perhaps there is a nebulous threshold below which effective research can work off of "throwaway" money and above which people start looking at money spent on research as "buying" something β€” we could call this point "expensive."

Another potential Achilles heel in this idea is the fact that often the work that convinces us outsiders that a research organization is effective is often some of the least existential-problem-addressing work that the organization does: transistors at Bell Labs, interactive computing at DARPA, etc. However, at the same time that it was inventing the transistor, Bell Labs was discovering better wire sheathings that saved AT&T billions of dollars, and DARPA was working out ways to detect nuclear explosions anywhere in the world at the same time that Licklider was seeding interactive computing groups across the US. This tension is worth noting because it's critical not to lash any single project too tightly to the importance of addressing existential threats at an organizational level.

So, the correct statement is perhaps that expensive research needs to address an existential threat eventually at an organizational level to maintain support. This is quite the mashup of nebulous words, isn't it? It's important enough that it's worthwhile to dig into each piece.

What does it mean for research to be "expensive'?

The line delineating "expensive" is relative and slippery, but there's definitely a line. In large part, it's psychological. Buying something expensive causes you to pause and consider. You care much more about its outcome. While your wealth level absolutely factors into what is expensive and not expensive, it's nothing like a 1:1 relationship. Someone who agonizes when cabbage prices go from $0.69/lb to $0.89/lb will buy a $500 phone without thinking about it. This same phenomenon happens with corporations, governments, investors, and philanthropists as well.

What does "eventually" entail?

Most organizations have a grace period to piddle around. However, like the border between expensive and not-expensive, the length of this grace period is extremely fuzzy and liable to change at a moment's notice. Usually, when it's confusing why a corporation or investor would be supporting work that is so far from a product, it doesn't mean you're missing something; it means the hammer is about to fall. It's almost indescribable, but there is a distinct sense you get from a startup or new research lab that suddenly runs into the end of its grace period β€” it goes from feeling like Willy Wonka's chocolate factory to ACME Chocolate Improvement Inc.

"Eventually" also raises a question about the frequency of hits that an organization needs to maintain, which seems to be a function of how big those hits are and how existential the threats they address actually are. DARPA has a 5–10% program success rate, which I suspect it can get away with because military superiority is very important to the US government, while most charities need to show progress every semi-annual fundraising season.

Why do existential threats need to be addressed at an organizational level?

The organization needs to address an existential threat to its money factory 36 rather than any individual project. Effective research organizations seem to build a portfolio of projects that address existential threats at a sufficient rate to maintain the perception that they're addressing existential threats.

This portfolio approach is clutch for several reasons. There is uncertainty around any given project as to whether it will address existential threats, and often, you can't honestly answer that question a priori without doing some work or strangling the project in the cradle. The book Loonshots introduces the concepts of "warty babies" and "the three deaths," which are incisive mental models of the phenomena that lead to project-cradle-death. Additionally, the projects that directly address existential threats for funders and those that are most interesting or globally impactful are often disjointed. AT&T didn't overwhelmingly benefit from the transistor or the cell phone, nor did Xerox benefit from the GUI. In the same way that winners pay for duds in a VC portfolio, aligned work can cover for misaligned work if the alignment is considered at an organizational instead of a project level.

If the organization produces aligned hits at a sufficient rate, it ideally can create a trusted hierarchy where the trust (and money) is flowing down the power ladder. Congress trusts the DARPA director, who trusts the deputy director, who trusts the PM. The PM doesn't need to get Congress's permission to start a program, just the permission of the deputy director. 38 This is why opacity is important to DARPA's outlier success β€” it can work on crazy ideas that would never get a priori funding from Congress, but it needs to continually renew the trust to maintain that opacity by delivering as an organization.

Another way this manifests is through contract research organizations that fund themselves through contracts or grants but use that money to fund internal research.

Industrial labs no longer fill the niche they did in the early-to-mid 20th century

In the past, industrial labs filled a particular niche in the innovation ecosystem. There's a strong sense that, as of 2021, corporate R&D organizations 39 no longer fill that niche. However, these organizations (including Xerox PARC and Bell Labs ) still exist, so we need a strong argument that they no longer fill the solutions R&D niche.

I'll proceed by both looking at outputs and inputs. Industrial labs are no longer producing the real-world outcomes they once did. However, that argument has a causality problem β€” it could be that labs are actually filling the same niche and a confounder is causing decreased output. This confounder could be the same thing driving stagnation in general. For example, if we really have picked a finite amount of low-hanging fruit and Robert Gordon is right that the explosion of growth between the late 19th and mid 20th century was a one-off event. I want to argue that, instead, the conditions that enabled industrial labs in particular to do great work no longer exist.

There are many exceptions! AI research in particular is a glaring exception to the decline of industrial labs, but there are many potentially amazing corporate R&D projects happening around the world. 40 One might argue that the exceptions are the rule β€” that there are just fewer technologies that would benefit from healthy industrial labs (remember the low-hanging fruit confounder). It's impossible to prove definitively, but I want to argue that the niche industrial labs once occupied still needs to be filled .

Going through the characteristics of the niche we discussed previously :

  • Most industrial labs no longer work on general-purpose technology. The trend is embodied by the founding memo Nathan Myhrvold wrote about Microsoft Research. The memo is quite good, and available here . In it, he explicitly focused Microsoft Research on advanced product development and not cutting-edge research. This trend is also seen at the organization formerly known as Google X, where they pride themselves on killing ideas quickly and then focusing on a specific product. The trend toward product development pushes corporate R&D more toward the same niche filled by startups.
  • Industrial labs no longer enable smooth transitions from crazy proofs of concept to manufactured products . Either the labs are so incredibly separate from the main organization that they have no advantage over a startup or are so tightly integrated that anything new is quashed. In the first case, there is no systematic way for projects to move from the lab to the main organization. Instead, they are forced to go through the same process of "finding a champion" and fighting a bespoke uphill battle that any product going to market faces. These barriers create the same Valley of Death that the academic project spinning out into a startup path faces. In the second case, labs are so joined at the hip to the main org that they can't work on anything besides incremental improvements. For more on the first case, see the section in Loonshots about "Manage the transfer, not the technology." For the second, see "Separate soldiers and scientists." (Have I convinced you to read it yet?)
  • Echoing the previous point, industrial labs often no longer work on potentially game-changing technologies with tight feedback loops . They're either doing show-off work that leads to nifty demos and papers or grungy incremental work. To posit a reason why: Technology improvement is no longer an existential imperative for most corporations. Today it's much easier for corporations to acquire new technology through M&A because of relaxed antitrust and a vibrant startup ecosystem. Modern corporations also face very different pressures from AT&T in the mid 20th century. AT&T benefited significantly from creating better technology both because it was the key blocker to its expansion and because the antitrust hammer was always waiting to drop if it didn't appear to be benefiting the public. See " Killing the Golden Goose? The changing nature of corporate research , 1980-2007" for an in-depth exploration of this trend.
  • Industrial labs no longer provide a first-class alternative to academia . With the exception of the big AI labs and maybe IBM research on superconductors, there are few areas where working at an industrial lab is as academically prestigious as being a professor. Like the shift away from game-changing technologies, I attribute the declining prestige to the fact that cutting-edge science and technology are no longer existential concerns for companies. The absence of an existential threat gives them little reason to hire and keep the best and most ambitious researchers, creating a downward spiral where there are no A players and the labs become susceptible to the fact that A players hire A players and B players hire C players. 44 Additionally, the incentive shift to focus more on product development has created a cultural shift away from participating in the scientific enterprise. See " The Decline of Science in Corporate R&D" for a more in-depth look.
  • Industrial labs no longer enable continuous work on 5+ year time scales . There is a lot of literature on corporate short-termism that I won't dig into. In short, most companies that have the resources to do research on a 5+ year timeline are disincentivized from speculative 5–10-year projects through a combination of focusing on quarterly earnings, competition, shareholders pushing companies to stick to their knitting, and the availability of M&A opportunities. Companies fail to support long-term research not just in the obvious sense that the projects get canceled or never started in the first place. The more insidious and common failure is that there's no level of planning for how promising projects eventually become part of the core company so even if they're not canceled, they putter along forever.
  • In most cases, industrial labs no longer probe deeply into natural phenomena and try to exploit them . Industrial labs just don't do as much science. This isn't to say that industrial labs ever pursued scientific discovery for its own sake, but in the past they perceived a direct line between scientific discoveries and the health of the company. I suspect that this perception is accurate in most cases! The move away from Pasteur's quadrant could simply be because we've exhausted exploitable phenomena and everything left is either too big, too small, or too obscure to make a difference at human time-and-size scales. Alternatively, the move could be chalked up to a change in the nature of the companies and their products to be more specialized and less dependent on exploiting new phenomena.

AI research is an exception to the decline of industrial labs

AI research bucks the trend of the decline of industrial labs as a place where globally important, cutting-edge work is done. If you squint, organizations like Facebook AI Research, Google Brain, DeepMind, and possibly OpenAI 46 bear strong resemblance to Bell Labs, Xerox PARC, and other legendary industrial labs in their heydays. It's worth understanding why this resemblance exists in these labs but not elsewhere to understand whether "creating the new Bell Labs" is a reasonable goal in other disciplines.

AI research can require massive resources β€” in this case, it's the thousands of dollars of compute for training models and creating massive datasets to train on. These resource requirements mean that there is exploratory research that people just can't do with the resources available to most labs at universities. As a result, industrial AI labs are a first-class alternative to academia with titans of the field like Yann LeCun and Samy Bengio joining FAIR and Google Brain, respectively. A similar effect pulled professors away from universities and into industrial labs in the first half of the 20th century.

At the same time, corporations running AI labs (reasonably) expect the research to create value commensurate to the costs of this research. Machine learning can directly improve the core product lines of all the companies listed above, in the same way that Bell Labs" work directly improved AT&T's "System." Additionally, AI promises massive value over long but not infinite time scales. OpenAI's business model is implicitly based on the assumption that they will create literally infinite value in the not unforeseeable future.

This alignment between their research and money factories allows modern AI labs to do highly regarded work and collaborate closely with academia without it seeming like a waste of money. Bell Labs provided a home for work that led to nine Nobel Prizes, often in collaboration with universities. Today, AI conferences are dominated by work from corporate AI labs, not just in quantity but quality as well.

Like the electronics work at Bell Labs, AI research benefits from having multiple disciplines in the same place with the people who will eventually produce it. When you're creating "AI for X]", it's generally helpful to have someone who is an expert in [X] around. Training and implementing ML algorithms at scale requires a different skill set than creating and prototyping the algorithms. Corporate AI labs have the budgets to hire research engineers, and also make it easy for researchers to talk to some of the best infrastructure and production engineers in the world. This dynamic roughly parallels the close ties between Bell Labs and Western Electric and is effectively the software version of ["Prototyping needs manufacturing in the room."

Perhaps the most uncomfortable parallel is between AT&T's status as a high-margin, cash-printing monopoly and Google or Facebook's similar situation. 47 AI labs provide more evidence that successful industrial labs can only exist in domains where there are large corporations with monopoly-like profits. The decline of industrial labs in chemistry- and physics-related domains may have been caused by commoditization of those products. GE, DuPont, Kodak, and others" share prices suggest that they at least are no longer perceived as monopolies. However, monopoly profits β†’ high-quality corporate research isn't the entire story, because you don't see a lot of high-quality non-product research coming out of Boeing or, arguably, Amazon. 48 Perhaps the missing difference is whether or not the corporation perceives that it will benefit from significantly better technology. AT&T benefited significantly from creating better technology because they had a pact with the government that as long as they kept making the system better and did public-benefiting research, they wouldn't be broken up. I wonder what the counterfactual is β€” if the government left them a monopoly without the pact. While Google and Facebook have no (publicly known) agreement with the government, arguably Google's ad-fueled profit does depend on them continuing to have the best search engine β€” people have no loyalty to Google beyond the quality of their searches. Similarly, one could make an argument that advertisers will abandon Facebook as soon as they have worse ad targeting or the kids move to another platform, like TikTok or Snap.

Microsoft is an interesting beast to examine through this lens. It's unconfirmed, but Microsoft Research (MSR) may have been started as a public offering in the same way Bell Labs was. Regardless, they explicitly set out to do more product-focused work than PARC, and Microsoft's cash cows were Windows and the Office Suite, both of which didn't benefit much from MSR work. MSR was subsequently pretty neglected and used for stunts like China expansion. However, Microsoft's core business has begun to shift toward cloud services, which do benefit from AI research, and it's becoming clear with things like GPT-3 that AI research can augment Office Suite products that are now actually under threat. This shift coincides with a partnership with OpenAI See " OpenAI forms exclusive computing partnership with Microsoft to build new Azure AI supercomputing technologies ." that looks a bit like the relationship between AT&T and Bell Labs if you squint. Amazon remains a challenge to this just-so story because it also has a massive cloud business but is not (publicly) doing as much speculative AI research.

This narrative suggests an uncomfortable truth. Instead of declining because of corporate short-termism, speculative corporate R&D might depend on companies with monopoly-like profits perceiving their fates as being intimately tied to a high-potential technology. This trifecta (monopoly profits + clearly high-potential technology + that technology being tied to the company's core business) can't be created by policy or even a cultural shift. The trifecta is the most straightforward answer to the question "Why hasn't Bell Labs been replicated?" and suggests that attempts to "create a new Bell Labs" are doomed to failure if they try to follow the playbook too closely. At the same time, I strongly suspect there are incredibly valuable technologies that don't clearly have high potential to solve an existential threat for a monopoly rentee but do need the environment and resources that were once provided by healthy industrial labs to realize that value.

The niche industrial labs once occupied still needs to be filled

Even if it's true that in the past industrial labs filled a particular niche in the innovation ecosystem , and tha industrial labs no longer fill the niche they did in the early-to-mid 20th century , it doesn't necessarily follow that the niche still exists or that it would be a good 50 idea to try to fill it. It's possible that we've pushed human capability to a point that has rendered the solutions R&D niche irrelevant. If we have truly unlocked every phenomenon it's possible to exploit, even Bell Labs in its full power would not have impressive output. However, I suspect this isn't the case.

It's hard to positively 51 answer the question "Is the niche once filled by industrial labs still valuable?" Part of the nature of solutions R&D is that valuable work is often not obvious. If we could point to an area of the adjacent possible The "adjacent possible" (grossly simplified) is the set of possible states that a system can enter, given its current state. In the case of science and technology, it's the set of things we could possibly invent and discover, given what we've already invented or discovered. The concept was originally introduced by Stuart Kauffman in his book Investigations . that is uncontroversially valuable, it arguably is no longer even solutions R&D. So it's hard to point to specific, clearly valuable solutions R&D areas that are not being tackled. Instead, I'm going to approach the question with the double-negative argument that we should not believe that the reason the niche has been vacated is because it is not valuable. I realize that's a bit convoluted. It's like a negative-space painting where I cannot portray the subjects directly but instead suggest their existence by filling in everything else.

First, let's take seriously the idea that the solutions R&D niche isn't valuable because we've picked all the low-hanging fruit that were once harvested by industrial labs. It has indeed been many years since we have unlocked a new physical phenomenon for exploitation in the same way we tapped the electron and steam before it. 53 It could be that we've exhausted exploitable phenomena and everything left is either too big, too small, or too obscure to make a difference at human time-and-size scales. If this is the case, the enterprise of discovery has become decoupled from the enterprise of invention, and while there are big discovery projects to be done, they will be purely for curiosity's sake. If this is the case, all the possible new inventions shouldn't require a lot of piddling around in disciplines that border on science. This argument is plausible. After all, companies with science-based products still have labs: 3M, Corning, Kodak, and others. One would expect that if there were fruits to be picked, these labs would be picking them. Instead, it looks like they're hanging out at the top of their respective S-curves and not producing new ones. DuPont gutting its once-legendary R&D department See " DuPont Will Dissolve Central Research." could be seen as a concession to this new state of the world.

However, there is also evidence that a world where industrial labs no longer fill the niche they once did was created by forces that were driven by shifting economic and cultural factors more than a depleted adjacent possible.

The decline of science in corporate R&D argues that increasing international competition and pressure from shareholders to specialize forced companies to decrease the scope of corporate R&D and shift toward more directly product-related work. The Microsoft Research memo is evidence for this scope shift β€” managers realized that Bell Labs and PARC-style R&D orgs were not actually great for business. Jettisoning industrial labs from a purely financial standpoint also makes sense when there are many perceived M&A opportunities to acquire new technology instead of developing it in-house. The decision is further supported when labs no longer function as monopoly-preserving peace offerings.

Few companies today meet the trifecta of conditions that healthy industrial labs require, and those that do are existentially tied to bit-based technologies more than atom-based technologies. The companies with science-based products that still have labs no longer command massive high-margin profits, forcing more conservative work that doesn't push far enough into the adjacent possible to unlock new high-margin S-curves. It's possible that the conditions for healthy industrial labs that focus on atom-based technologies could occur again, but creating those conditions requires so many other contingent things to happen first that it won't happen anytime soon. For example, it's possible to imagine a world where a company has mastered a high-margin application of molecular machines, and to keep its edge it needs to push ever farther into the realms of atomically precise manufacturing. However, even if that company were to start today, it would take a decade before it was at a point where it could create a healthy industrial lab.

What about government labs? We haven't talked about them much, but government research is basically corporate R&D for United States Inc. If there were valuable parts of the adjacent possible that industrial labs could explore, shouldn't we expect government labs to be filling the solutions R&D niche? Yes and no. The US government technically meets the conditions for healthy industrial labs β€” it's a monopoly and benefits from value created in the US. As one would expect, in areas where America feels an existential threat, National Labs and other government research organizations do actually look like healthy industrial labs. However, there are fewer areas where research can address existential risk for a country than you might expect! If you look at National Labs through the lens that Alignment requires existential threats," everything makes more sense; National Labs 55 excel at work related to nuclear weapons and military capability in general. Perhaps a bit cynically, arguably everything else National Labs do is a nice-to-have but doesn't address an existential threat to the government.

It's impossible to rule out the grim possibility that we have depleted the areas of the adjacent possible that solutions R&D can reach. However, there is strong evidence that even if there were fertile ground, industrial labs (including those of United States Inc.) would not be cultivating it. In this case, it's up to other institutions to step boldly into the void.

Existing Institutional Structures are Inadequate

In the late 20th century and early 21st century, industrial labs yielded more and more of their niche to a combination of academia and newfangled "startups." You can see this change in data on scientific publications (which have gone through the roof in academia but steadily declined in companies, suggesting that researchy work has consolidated in academia) or the number of mergers and acquisitions (also through the roof, suggesting that large companies have increasingly outsourced early-stage engineering work to startups). See " The Decline of Science in Corporate R&D " again. A less rigorous but more powerful way to see the change is by cultural pattern-matching β€” that the sorts of projects that you would once have expected to find in an industrial lab are now either in academic labs or startups. Many people implicitly or explicitly believe that between academia and startups 57 the solutions R&D niche is filled. I once believed that myself, but came to realize that there are many projects that don't fit within the constraints of either academia or startups. "Things that are too engineering-heavy for academia and too researchy for startups" is shorthand for one class of these projects. 58 By unpacking that term, I hope to convince you that the combination of startups and academia is insufficient to occupy the niche once served by industrial labs.

Academia revolves around scientific inquiry

A quick aside : "Academia" is a nebulous term. It doesn't strictly refer to universities. Instead, I use "academia" to cover all the people and institutions who are playing the incentive game where you get points for papers, citations, and general adulation from other people who are playing that same game. In this sense, you can participate in academia partially; there are some professors who are barely part of it beyond their institutional ties; there are people with jobs entirely unrelated to research who nevertheless are driven by academia's incentives.

The academic model is built around scientific inquiry. Academics are rewarded for moving information up the ladder of abstraction. See http://worrydream.com/LadderOfAbstraction/ . The more general your theory or technique, the more you are praised. Unfortunately, the academic reward system is at odds with the engineering design work you need to create useful products.

A schematic of scientific inquiry vs. engineering design from Radical Abundance.

In Radical Abundance , Eric Drexler presents this incredible chart that captures the contrasting dynamics of scientific inquiry and engineering design. In a nutshell, scientific inquiry is a process where information flows from the concrete to the abstract, ideally resulting in an abstract model β€” the more general, the better; engineering design is a process where information flows from the abstract to the concrete, ideally resulting in a physical system β€” the more useful the better. Neither of these processes "precedes" the other. 60

Moving down the ladder of abstraction clashes with academic incentives that have been set up to support scientific inquiry. As a result, academic engineers default to creating proofs of concept not as a step toward a working system but for the sole purpose of validating general engineering principles or design concepts. The whole working system is left as an exercise to the reader. Proofs of concept, general principles, and designs are important! But they are a long way from a useful thing out in the world. For context, proof of concept is level three of nine on NASA's Technology Readiness Scale. See https://benjaminreinhardt.com/trl . More importantly, a proof of concept usually isn't enough for a technology to gain momentum by attracting the money and effort to continue the process of engineering design. Here is where the Valley of Death raises its head again.

Because academic engineering focuses on the top of the ladder of abstraction, feedback loops that can only come from implementation are rare. A design can check all the boxes on a list of requirements (which makes it great for a paper) but completely fail to be a useful system. 62 My favorite example of this takes us back to the example in Prototyping needs manufacturing in the room": Recall how perfect right angles in cutouts are completely free (and the default!) in a CAD model but are extremely hard to machine correctly. These weirdly important implementation details are usually tacit knowledge that does not exist at higher levels of abstraction. It gets "abstracted away.'

Novelty is an important tool for moving up the ladder of abstraction, but it can be a wrench in the gears of useful engineering design. When your goal is abstract knowledge, anything that's fully captured by existing understanding is worthless. As a result, academic work is always judged by "What are the new ideas here?" rather than "Does it work?" On the other hand, a reliability and success-maximizing engineering rule of thumb is to use as few new things as possible to get the system to work. This tension means that academic engineers will not work on some ideas or bolt on unnecessary fancy techniques. Welding together a bunch of old ideas to get something to work is great engineering practice, but it doesn't create any general academic insight and thus doesn't lead to papers, promotion, or tenure.

At the end of the day, ideas need to come out of a single mind. The abstract models at the pinnacle of scientific inquiry are effectively just well-justified ideas. Scientific mythology has further solidified the paradigm of theory leaping forth from a single great mind like Athena from the head of Zeus. Newton, Einstein, Curie ... As a result, 63 academic culture prizes individual recognition, not team output. In academia, citations and (especially first) authorships on papers are the coin of the realm. These status and reward mechanisms push people to make sure each piece of their work is recognized. Many engineering projects require "teamwork" in the sense of putting your head down and doing the unsexy work that needs to be done without remembering who did what. This isn't to say that academics won't do unsexy work, 64 but it does need to culminate in something paper-worthy.

There are an increasing number of academic papers with large numbers of authors, but there is a roughly constant amount of "esteem currency" per paper, so the career capital per author decreases as the number of authors increases. See " Paper Authorship Goes Hyper ." Contrast the incentives in academia to professional engineering, where reward (both status and monetary) is usually invariant to the number of people on the project. When someone says "I helped build the Falcon 9 Rocket" or "My instrument is on the Perseverance Rover," nobody asks, "Ah, but how many other people also worked on it? Were you first author?" It's viscerally cool even if you just tested one non-critical part. When "Does it work?" is the biggest source of recognition, the incentive is to have as many people working on a project as necessary to make it work.

Academic constraints

In order to build up our pattern-matching, it's useful to explicitly enumerate the constraints that define the nebulous edge of academia's reach. By rights, this list needs its own piece, and we touched on several of these points already, but they bear repeating.

A lot of engineering work is not novel. Spend enough time in research seminars, and you'll inevitably hear many variations on both "Our work is novel because..." and "Yes, but it's not really novel, is it?" The word "novel" is used as an idea bludgeon in academia and weeds out many classes of ideas.

A non-exhaustive list of what gets discarded by the novelty filter:

  • New approaches to old, "solved" problems.
  • Better implementations of an idea that's already been implemented.
  • Efficiency improvements along a different metric than the ones the field normally cares about.
  • Scaling existing techniques.
  • Creating something for a specific applicationn as opposed to a general principle or purpose.
  • Further work on things that have already gotten to proofs of concept.
  • Integrating several already-existing ideas into a single system.
  1. engineering does not always get many citations. Even if work is novel enough to be published, low-citation ideas languish in obscurity. It's valid to ask, "Are there things that are valuable that don't get a lot of citations?"Absolutely. Valuable projects that want to live in an academic lab but wouldn't get many citations include:
  • Projects that are intermediate steps to a larger vision without a strong conclusion besides "We did a thing!"
  • Engineering work in a theory-heavy field or theory work in an engineering-heavy field. More generally, work in a field that the field doesn't think is valuable.
  • Ideas that are far out of mainstream. Even non-malicious people often don't have the bandwidth to dig in and see if an idea from left field is worthwhile or utter crackpottery. It's usually the latter, so the default answer is no. (See the point about stepping too far outside the mainstream below.)

Engineering just asks, "Does it work?" In academia, it's hard to publish ideas that are too outside of the approved way of doing things. Kuhnian paradigms outline a set of questions and the rules around answering them. See The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Ideas can stray too far outside of accepted paradigms when they're asking different questions, or measure success differently than the ways the paradigm prescribes. Boyden et al.'s work with expansion microscopy See " Expansion Microscopy ." is a good example: Instead of asking, "How good can we make a microscope's resolution?" they asked, "How big can we expand a sample while maintaining its structure?" 68 It's also hard to publish work that doesn't fit cleanly into a disciplinary box. I want to use the term "antedisciplinary science" from Sean R. Eddy's article of the same name but relegated it to this footnote to avoid too many new words. It's too much like discipline X to be published in a journal for discipline Y, but it's too much like discipline Y to be published in a journal for discipline X. This situation is of course tricky because many (most?) ideas that go outside of established paradigms are crackpottery.

It's hard to write a paper if you can't even get the money to do the research. The need to align with current funding priorities is particularly pernicious in academia because most grant processes depend on politics and committees. By their nature, committees lead to median results, so committee-mediated grants will rarely fund unsexy outlier work. One reason to write papers is to continue playing the game, so if a paper doesn't hint at your continued ability to do work that aligns with funding priorities, there's less incentive to write it.

A project is unlikely to lead to a paper if it's not within scope for a PhD student or untenured professor. Graduate students are the labor force in academic science and engineering. In exchange for cheap labor, grad students expect to produce research within a 4–7-year time frame that can help them move on to the next rung of the academic career ladder. 70 While a tenured professor might be willing to work on something crazy that will take 10 years and could be a complete dud, no grad student would rationally work on it and no advisor with a student's best interest at heart would ask them to. The incentive for PhD students to produce high-impact papers for the sake of their careers amplifies all the other constraints; PhD students in science get most of their funding through research grants, so their work is especially susceptible to grant-related constraints.

Projects whose outputs are structured data or reusable code don't lend themselves to papers. Academic papers are built around the process of scientific inquiry, where collecting data and writing code are only in service of producing an abstract model or theory β€” the more generalizable the better. There is little reward to producing high-quality, reusable datasets or code, despite the value they can create.

A project is unlikely to lead to a paper if it involves a lot of coordination. Academia emphasizes individual agency. This is a good thing, but if a project cannot be effectively modularized, it will end up requiring a lot of grungy coordination work that doesn't count as a contribution unless you're in charge of the project. A big reason to go into academia in the first place is to avoid having a boss and because you like doing your own thing your own way. Obviously, there are exceptions like the LHC, but that is a situation where the experimental particle physicists are locked into a paradigm and have no other option.

Coordination aversion hits especially hard projects that don't fit into a particular disciplinary bucket or require integration between components built in different labs. Projects of a particular scale require coordination by their very nature.

Startups revolve around growth

A startup is a company designed to grow fast. Being newly founded does not in itself make a company a startup. Nor is it necessary for a startup to work on technology, or take venture funding, or have some sort of "exit." The only essential thing is growth. Everything else we associate with startups follows from growth.

β€”Paul Graham, "Startup = Growth" http://paulgraham.com/growth.html .

Just as academia revolves around scientific inquiry, startups revolve around growth. In our context β€” filling the solutions R&D niche β€” this focus on growth creates several corollaries. Obviously, it does mean we're talking about companies that work on technology. And not just software-driven, scalable-business "tech" but actual technology. A technology startup is unlikely to be able to fund development by selling products from day one. The company then needs to take investment, short of extraordinary circumstances, like being run by a multimillionaire or some kind of absurd government contract that pays in advance. The only people who will make that kind of investment are institutional VCs and individual angel investors. Raising VC money then commits a startup to have some sort of "exit." So, for our purposes, "startup" means "VC-funded startup," along with the consequent constraints. 72

The coupling between startups and growth raises the reasonable question: What about low-growth small businesses? As we noted earlier the nature of innovation orgs makes them dependent on an external money factory . If a small business is doing self-directed R&D, they can't depend on its results for free cash flow. If the company raises money, it implicitly binds itself to all the startup constraints we will dig into shortly, even if it does not consider itself a high-growth startup. If the company forgoes investment and the founders are not extremely wealthy (e.g.: SpaceX), the company needs early revenue from somewhere. The common move for bootstrapped companies that need to do more development is to do consulting work to generate revenue that they then plow into development. Unless it's wildly profitable, the consulting approach severely limits the amount of time and money that can be spent on development, possibly dragging it out forever. SBIR grants are another option, but they are relatively small (order $1M over several years) and have the same effect as consulting with small companies limping from one grant to the next. Some projects need effort above a certain threshold to move forward!

Startup constraints

Similar to the constraints on academia, this list deserves its own piece! This list is meant to enumerate the constraints on startups specifically in the context of solutions R&D.

Startups need a convincing story for how the project's output produces a massive and competitive return on investment over a reasonable time scale. The long-tailed nature of startup investing means that venture capitalists need to believe that any investment in their portfolio could potentially return the fund. But it's not even enough to have great returns β€” you need to have the best returns! That is, VCs don't need to hit an absolute benchmark but instead need to compete against other assets like the stock market for LP (i.e., their investors) dollars. If the stock market is absolutely crushing it, LPs have less incentive to invest in higher-risk assets like tech startups. As a result, VCs need to do everything in their power to maximize their ROI, which includes not just how much they grew the principal but how long that growth took. As a result, the same dynamic plays out "one level lower" with VCs now in the role the LPs once held. Many atom-based technologies have the same or higher risk as a software startup but require more capital and have longer timelines. The cold, hard numbers often make SaaS businesses a better investment.

Startups need to move fast. J. C. R. Licklider kicked off work on the ARPA program that would go on to build what we would consider "modern computing" in 1962. Perhaps the first real "value capture" event it led to was Apple's IPO in 1980. This trajectory would have been untenable as a startup. While there is flexibility if a project's valuation continues going through the roof, VC fund structure pushes for returns on 5–7-year time horizons. Venture timescales often lead to projects being pushed to focus on a specific application or being acquired before achieving the technical goals they set out to hit. There is nothing wrong with focus or acquisition, per se, but they can lead to technologies failing to live up to their potential.

Startups need to capture the value they create. Markets are great, but there is no law of economics that people can always capture the value they create if they are clever enough. "We conclude that only a miniscule fraction of the social returns from technological advances over the 1948-2001 period was captured by producers" β€” William D. Nordhaous, " Schumpeterian Profits in the American Economy: Theory and Measurement ." Innovation requires multiple people. Often, the person who figures out how to make a lot of money off of a discovery or invention is not the person who created it, nor are they even in the same organization.

Innovations that change one or more components of a bigger system or process often make poor startups. A startup that is trying to improve or change a component of a bigger system has two options. It either needs to convince whoever runs that system to adopt the change (which is especially hard when no particular entity runs the system) or to build the entire system themselves with the change incorporated. Obviously, the change needs to happen eventually, but many paradigm shifts (especially in complex systems) initially lower performance, at least on traditional metrics. Change happens either when the new paradigm has the time and resources it needs to catch up to the old way of doing things or people pay attention to new metrics where the new paradigm performs well. The latter usually only happens if they can see the new paradigm in action and realize that the traditional metrics weren't capturing all the important features of the system. Both of these options are hard for a startup to pull off because each approach requires significant time and resources before even getting hints of traction. It's hard to get that time and resources because potential customers (the people running the systems or consuming their outputs) will assert that the idea is dumb right up until it's not.

Some innovations are just hard to productize. Process innovations often fall into this category See " Fundamental Manufacturing Process Innovation Changes the World ." β€” especially those that don't depend on new technology, per se, but on a new way of doing the same thing with basically the same tools. The Bessemer process, for example, used the same crucibles, but you put different materials in them. Social process changes (like Toyota's Kaizen method ) are even harder to productize. In these situations, the vast majority of the value generally accrues to the end user. The obvious advice would be to start a firm that's doing the end-to-end thing and outcompete the incumbents. While that should theoretically work, it often runs into the reality of extremely complex products that you would need to reinvent from the ground up (like if you had a better way of making passenger jets) or heavily regulated industries where it would take massive lobbying just to use a new process. A startup doesn't usually have the time or resources to tackle these scenarios. The alternative approach is to take on a change-management consulting role, which usually doesn't capture enough value to be VC-fundable, so it needs to be profitable early on. Additionally, consulting runs headlong into the bootstrapping issues we already discussed.

Startups shouldn't tackle market, channel, AND technical risk. New technological paradigms usually face all three of technical, market, and channel risk. You simultaneously need to develop the technology to a point where it's competitive with alternatives, figure out who wants to use it, and establish how they're going to buy it. All three are herculean tasks.

It's common wisdom among VCs that it's not a good idea to invest in companies that are taking on more than one of these risks. In addition, Jerry Neumann argues convincingly that VCs rationally should avoid technical risk in " Productive Uncertainty ." This heuristic isn't misguided. The chance of failure goes up dramatically when an organization tries to tackle two, let alone three, of those risks. Startups should only tackle one (or maybe two). The reason therapeutics-focused startups can exist is that they have almost no channel or market risk; there is a well-established pipeline from lab to acquisition by a pharma company, and insurance companies are guaranteed to pay for drugs that go through FDA approval and target big conditions.

At the end of the day, the work you need to do to drive adoption of a technology is often very different from getting it to a certain performance level. The work priorities drive the type of organization you create. As much as we like to think that startups are about building technology, they are actually about selling technology and adopting it for specific markets so that they can do that better.

Misconceptions about things that are too engineering-heavy for academia and too researchy for startups

It's common to use wacky ideas and long-term projects as examples of things that fall outside of both academic and startup constraints. This belief is pernicious because there are many examples of both getting support; people hold those examples up as evidence that the whole class of things that don't fit into academia or startups doesn't exist.

  • Long-term projects get support if they hit consistent milestones, and they'll be able to capture a lot of the value they create if they succeed.
  • Wacky ideas get support as long as they don't threaten paradigms too much or someone thinks they can make money off of them.
  • Research projects that require a lot of people or coordination as long as the final product is a paper they can all put their names on.
  • Research projects that require some engineering effort as long as the engineering effort resembles something that has been done before: building a bigger telescope/particle collider/linear accelerator/space probe, etc.

What is the relationship between profit, value capture, and impact in the context of invention and discovery?

Lurking in the firmament above any question of institutional homes for researchy activities is the question of profit and value capture. Academic work is usually profit-agnostic and defaults toward being "open" in a way that often clashes with capturing the value of the work. Startup work needs to be eventually-profitable so it defaults toward work whose value can be captured. Stepping outside of existing institutional structures creates a dazzling array of possible trade-offs. Profit incentivizes people and funds work but can warp incentives and feedback loops. Value capture creates profit but can constrain diffusion and types of work. Context attenuates all of these trad-eoffs!

If you want to maximize the amount of awesome, joy, and wonder that technology work creates (which I'll just refer to with the horrible but useful shorthand "impact"), what is the correct approach to profit and value capture? The topic quickly becomes ideologically saturated β€” some people view profit as ritually unclean, and others see it as just rewards or even a key metric for virtuous actions.

I want to step orthogonally to this ideological spectrum and unpack the question: What is the relationship between profit, value capture, and impact in the context of invention and discovery? Attacking this question isn't just idle philosophizing; it can be a compass for navigating the idea maze by giving a sense of high-level direction while navigating around practical obstacles like figuring out how money works at a new kind of innovation organization.

Profit is important for both practical and ideological reasons

Practically , profit increases organizational longevity and robustness because it means the organization is getting paid directly for what it does. 76 In other words, profit makes organizations autocatalyzing . Profit is the most straightforward way for an organization to both keep doing what it's doing and possibly do more of it. If the organization is doing good work, profit is the most straightforward way for them to continue!

Profit also lowers the opportunity cost of working on a project. As of 2021, most people who have the skills to do important solutions R&D work always have much better opportunities both in terms of pay and status. They could either start a startup and roll the dice on a massive outcome or go work at a big tech company, get a position in finance, 77 or become a management consultant β€” all places where paychecks have the possibility of being huge and there really isn't any hit to prestige. Nonprofits and government organizations usually have significantly diminished pay scales because of tight budgets and convention. Anecdotally, forgone salaries are one of the biggest deterrents that keep people from becoming DARPA program managers. While many people do forgo higher salaries to do important work, many of them can only sustain the discomfort for so long. For other excellent people, the opportunity cost is too high. Profit enables an organization to pay higher salaries, which in turn reduces opportunity cost. If more activities could be profitable, that could lower opportunity costs for excellent people to work on a more diverse set of things.

Ideologically, there is a sense of justice when organizations and people who make the world better are rewarded. "Doing good is its own reward" is not untrue, but it would be lovely if profitability matched up more closely with value creation. It seems a little "off" that companies like Peloton (just to name an example and not to call them out specifically) are valued at billions of dollars in large part because of technologies like screens, GUIs, and internet connectivity, while the people who originally created those technologies aren't particularly wealthy. Anecdotally, I believe Robert Metcalfe is the only former PARC employee who became a centimillionaire, and to my knowledge, no Bell Labs employees became fabulously wealthy from the work they did there. 78

Enabling (or at least not maligning) profit from world-improving activities is a key that unlocks both profit's practical and ideological benefits. However, there's a (perhaps productive) tension between whether profit should be an instrumental or intrinsic goal. Profit as an instrumental goal is the stance that "ultimately we want more amazing things and profit is an important tool to encourage people to make those things." Profit as an intrinsic goal is the stance that "profit is the just reward for creating amazing things." The latter can problematically bleed into the stance that "any created value can and should be captured."

Those of us who primarily care about enabling more amazing things in the world should be wary of this last point because it comes along with the corollary "And therefore, if you can't capture value, you must be missing something, or it wasn't worthwhile in the first place." Most of you probably don't believe the extreme corollary explicitly. However, it does tend to implicitly pervade the discourse ,so I'm going to spend a good chunk of time arguing against it. But before I do, I want to argue that while profit isn't an end goal like the Golden Fleece, it's also not a complete trap like the Hand of Midas. It's important to acknowledge that profit is critical for both organizational longevity and for technology to diffuse into the world at all!

Profit makes organizations autocatalyzing

Autocatalytic reactions are (chemical) reactions that produce at least one of their own reactants. Autocatalytic reactions are complicated!

Producing some of their own reactants makes autocatalytic reactions easier to sustain than other reactions. Arguably, life itself is one giant autocatalytic reaction. Profitable organizations are autocatalytic reactions because they produce the key ingredient you need to keep an organization going: money. In effect, profitable organizations become their own money factory . Autocatalytic organizations are more robust and ultimately have more leeway to take unconventional actions.

Profit gives an organization as much control of its own fate as possible. A profitable business has many different "moves" at its disposal that it can use to survive. It can build up cash reserves to hold it through down markets; it can sell stock to raise cash; it can shift products to adjust to changing demand; it can grow or shrink depending on need. All of these moves are possible with minimal regulatory restriction or third-party permission. These moves can increase organizational longevity, which in turn can enable an organization to take on long-term projects that would otherwise be off the table. In addition, larger profit margins translate to more slack in the system for unconventional actions. Low-margin organizations (rationally) avoid rocking the boat because they can quickly become unprofitable, while high-margin organizations can afford failed experiments.

On the other hand, if you are funding operations from sources besides profit, you're obligated to one or more entities that care about something besides the organization's output. Some of these sources include purchasing debt, selling equity, or soliciting donations. Ideally, incentives are aligned even in this situation, but "reaper functions" Peter van Hardenberg minted this excellent term. β€” the real reasons, often unspoken, why people are promoted or fired β€” dominate other incentives. At the end of the day, equity investors care about their share prices going up, debtors care about being paid back, and donors care about feeling good.

The only way for an organization to become autocatalyzing without being profitable would be to somehow amass a war chest large enough to fund operations out of interest on its principal. Looking at a list of the longest-lived organizations in the world, they're overwhelmingly profitable companies that make and sell goods people want (usually food or alcohol) and universities with endowments. See " The Data of Long-lived Institutions ."

On top of flexibility and long-term survivability, profit also creates an extremely tight feedback loop between an organization and the outside world. Jason Crawford argues that cash flow also creates the tightest possible feedback loop with the world outside the organization. Arguably, cold, hard cash is one of the only metrics that isn't automatically subject to Goodhart's Law " When a measure becomes a target, it ceases to be a good measure ." β€” if your organization's goal is genuinely selling a product or service, profit is a hard metric to game short of literal fraud.

While it's nowhere near as useful as actual profit, aiming for eventual profitability can still contribute to organizational longevity. Practically, it's both easier and less organizationally risky to raise capital if you're aiming to become (or better yet, are) profitable. Many people are more open to parting with their money if they think of it as an investment instead of a donation. And obviously, the less uncertain and closer to the present that profit is, the less you need to pay for that money. In the context of talking to people about riffing on ARPA, I've gotten "Can I invest?"many times, but rarely "Can I donate?" Of course, targeting eventual profitability can also backfire from an organizational longevity point of view!

The trick is threading the needle between organizational goals and what people will actually pay for. We tend to laud organizations that have pulled this off β€” they become household names, like Apple, SpaceX, and Zappos. It's pretty clear that they are better equipped to deliver delightful electronics, spaceflight, and internet shoes than a nonprofit with the same goals. Alignment is easy if your organizational goal is "make as much money as possible," but that is often not the case for organizations in the 21st century that are often started to fulfill some mission "and make money while doing it." Most of you reading this probably lean toward the latter category. I suspect that an underlying point of disagreement between people who laud profit and those who denounce it is over how feasible it is to align organizational goals and profitability. It's easy to to get sucked to one end of the spectrum or the other: either the view that it's possible to align profit and other goals in almost every situation or that profit inevitably distracts from other goals. Like most dichotomies in complex systems, the answer is, "It depends."

Someone needs to buy manufactured technology eventually in a monetized economy

Profit is also an integral part of getting technology out into the world. The only way that a technology ends up being used by people who didn't build it is if it's sold or given away. The former situation is far more common. In either situation, technology needs to be "productized" β€” ie., made legible and useful for people outside the organization. If it is going to be sold on an open market, it also needs to be "commercialized," i.e., made cheap and desirable enough that it makes sense to sell it in the first place. Empirically, profit-seeking organizations have much stronger incentives to do commercialization well. As a result, profit is almost always part of technology out into the world.

There are exceptions, of course. The major exception happens when a technology is created and used entirely internally to an organization. Many of the internal tools used at Google are entirely created, manufactured, and used internally. Other exceptions, like open-source software, are harder to categorize. Firms create technology barter deals with one other. At-home manufacturing completely breaks the model. (Although arguably that would just be a trend toward a less monetized economy, rather than an exception to the rule.)

It's a common perception that the military creates internal technology similar to Google and sits outside the market as an unmoved mover of technology. The US government's version of internal technology creation is less clean than Google's. The government does own R&D labs it uses to create some technology that it specifically needs. However, the government contracts out much of its R&D and all of its manufacturing to external firms (as opposed to owning the manufacturing plant and giving it a budget). 83 So even military technology is purchased eventually. The firms that sell to the military need to pay their bills, so the costs do matter (though cost-plus contracting distorts this). If the military paid less than the cost of the goods, the firms would go out of business. While the US military spends hundreds of billions of dollars a year ($934B in 2019), it does not have infinite money. So while they are weaker, I'd argue that the forces of market discipline do act on military technology β€” if it becomes cheaper for the same quality, it will be used more.

If this view is correct, it means that in a monetized economy, commercialization is an essential step on a technology's path to adoption. There is an implicit feeling among some technologists 84 that commercialization is a lesser activity for people just out to make money. Instead, it should be seen as a critical part of the cycle.

Market discipline is a double-edged sword

Markets are implicitly entangled in any line of thought around commercialization and profit. They are, of course, where you buy and sell goods.

The most interesting thing about markets for thinking about enabling better solutions R&D (and invention and discovery more generally) is market discipline. Rather than the narrow, technical definition that nobody knows, I'll be using it in the colloquial, nebulous sense of: "She wanted to build an entire new computing ecosystem, but market discipline forced her to release subpar imitation of existing products"; "Resisting market discipline, she built the technology everybody thought was stupid but turned out amazing in the end"; "Market discipline honed the organization into a lean, mean, product-producing machine." Market discipline can make organizations strong and efficient, but it can also crush eventually-productive creativity. Discipline enabled the Spartans to crush the Athenians in the Peloponnesian War, but do we want a world made of only Spartas?

Decoupling from market discipline is like cave diving

Note that I have never gone cave diving. I am not that cool.

Market discipline is embodied in Y Combinator's motto: "Make something people want." It's a good heuristic for hewing to market discipline even before making money. Paradoxically, there are many counter-aphorisms, like the apocryphal Henry Ford quote, "If I asked people what they wanted, they would have said "a faster horse.'" The resolution to this paradox is, "Make something people want at some point in the future." In the long run, someone needs to buy something downstream of any "useful" work, so by definition they need to want it! However, the whole time you're not making something people want, you are burning resources. The question then becomes: What is the thing people want in the future and can the technology or idea survive long enough to get there?

Cave diving feels like a great analogy for the process. While you're going through the cave, you're using oxygen. If you run out before you reach the next air pocket, you're dead. Working on a product you can always test against the market is like normal diving β€” you can always come up for air, and maybe you need to get the timing right so you don't get the bends.

Perhaps it's torturing the analogy, but there are some interesting concepts to pull back from cave diving. The longer the path, the better you need to plan. If it's a short hop and you can see where you're aiming, you don't need to plan as much. If you know that there are lots of possible air pockets, you have the freedom to explore more. Similarly, if the technology has lots of market "exit ramps," you can do more exploration. Software is uniquely repurposable which might offer an explanation for why agile product development makes sense for software but perhaps not in other situations. Having a precise idea of where you're going is very important. Even if you don't know the exact way, you need to keep your bearings toward where you're going.

Many of DARPA's outlier results were things that nobody was asking for

DARPA works on programs that go against the established paradigm. DARPA has worked on things unasked for by both the military and industry. Often people who have become comfortable with one way of doing something are not asking for them to come in and change it or actively resist the change.

Three examples of this are:

1. Drones : DARPA had a drone program in the 80s. DARPA transferred the program to the Navy where it was discontinued, but DARPA continued to work on drones until the military paradigm shifted and suddenly they were incredibly useful.

2. Optoelectronics : In this case, it was businesses that weren't asking for optical multiplexing. AT&T and IBM had worked on multiplexing but had budget crunches and didn't see value in it. DARPA supported optoelectronics work from 1985 to 2005 (20 years!).

3. Personal computers : Nobody was asking for most of the pieces of the Mother of All Demos. The Mother of All Demos was Douglas Engelbart's 1968 tour de force in which he demonstrated the majority of what has become modern computing. Instead of collaborative shopping lists and voice calls, the military wanted a computer that could help commanders understand what was happening with nukes and battles.

The upshot is that you can't apply the normal maxim of "Make something people want" to an ARPA program and seek out "customer validation." This missing feedback loop is tricky because you do need to make something people want ... eventually.

Profit maximization can hamstring technologies whose impact depends on them spreading as far as possible

Profit-focused organizations are incentivized to try to capture as much of the value they create as possible. At the end of the day, both a startup's valuation and a corporation's share price are both theoretically based on future cash flows and profits. Of course, profit-maximizing organizations are not mindless greed-monsters. In many situations, giving up short-term profit can actually lead to longer-term revenue. Ideally, these organizations would be able to sit at some point on the trade-off curve that maximized value by maximizing impact. Profit-maximizing organizational structures can also be the best way to support a technology!

However, there are four mechanisms that can lead to for-profit companies hamstringing technological advancement, despite other aspirations.

1. Specialization: Generally, it's a good idea for a for-profit business to start with a single product and a specific market or niche. This good business practice means that outside of a large company with an R&D department, most of the development work should be focused on productizing a technology for a specific task. Startups who want to start by building a platform or doing all the things tend to go down in glory-seeking flames. Specializing technology for a specific task is not inherently a bad thing! It's also possible to thread the narrow path of increasing generality, starting from a small niche and jumping to bigger and bigger applications over time. Elon Musk is the master of this. However, companies rarely avoid getting stuck in one of those niches, especially if the niche isn't profitable enough to support R&D on the more general technology. This situation happens all the time to university spinoff technology; it often needs more general development to reach a certain performance threshold, but it gets stuck in a niche in order to build a company. I've seen this trap ensnare everything from multi-material 3D printers to biosensors and home robots.

2. Investor pressures: For-profit companies working on technology generally need investors because they won't turn a profit for at least several years after getting started. These investors have their own incentives, and maximizing the impact of a technology generally is not the most important one. Investors can have specific timelines for an exit, need to show growth to their investors in order to raise a new round, or just have opinions about where the technology should go that conflict with maximizing impact. (Of course, any source of money comes along with its own set of pressures!)

3. Capturing value: For-profit companies need to capture some value that they create! It is rare that an organization can both forgo significant value by making key parts of a technology public and make money at a rate that both satisfies investors and can fund the development of general-purpose technologies. I will argue later that there is a significant class of innovations that would create drastically less value for the world if their value had been captured by their creators .

4. Speed : An organization could detect all of the traps listed above and forgo trying to maximize profit, not take investment, and make most of its technology work public, pulling in revenue through non-exclusive license fees and consulting work. Unfortunately, this strategy can hamstring the technology you're working on in a different way, limiting general-purpose development to the work that can be done when you have particularly lucrative contracts. As a result, technology development slows to a crawl. Many aerospace technologies seem to get stuck in this particular trap!

We stand on the shoulders of too many giants to give them all credit

If you wish to make an apple pie from scratch, you must first invent the universe.

β€”Carl Sagan

Should the neighbor who had a cross-fence conversation about a process she uses at work that sparked the realization that led to the invention capture some value? She was certainly instrumental to its success. What about the technician who knew how to twist the wire in just the right way to get the first proof of concept to work?

And what about all the failed projects that left a pile of skeletons indicating where the traps were?

It might be possible for software companies to go through their tech stacks and enumerate the open-source projects that they use and who contributed to those. However, there is still a ton of illegibility around what fraction of the value each project contributes, how much each contributor to the project contributed, and a million other considerations. And outside of software it gets even more gnarly.

The multiplicity of people involved in creation leads to a contradiction that I suspect is fundamentally unresolvable.

On the one hand, one person or class of people do not deserve credit for an innovation. The iPhone needed Jobs and Ive and all the engineers and designers at Apple and the team at Xerox PARC and all the people who invented the transistor and all the folks at Intel and other places who made it cheap and everybody at Corning who made gorilla glass and ...

On the other hand, credit is really important for motivating people and enabling us to wrap our human brains around the world.

It is hard to capture value from research

Knowledge is non-rivalrous. Your knowledge of airplane building does not prevent me from knowing how to build an airplane. Once knowledge is no longer secret, it generally becomes non-excludable as well. As a result, a lot of research resembles a public good. 86

At the same time, value capture is important for incentivizing and funding research. At an organizational level, it's easier to fund research if it there's a chance will eventually generate returns. At an individual level, money is coupled to both status and quality of life. People with the skills to do research often have lucrative alternatives. So all things held equal, capturing the value from research is useful. Unfortunately, all things are not held equal.

The primary way to capture a public good's value is to privatize it. However, privatizing research is tricky. Current value capture mechanisms are crude β€” to capture value from research, you need to either patent it and enforce that patent or build a product around it. Researchers and research organizations can also indirectly capture some of the value they create through credit and status that can convert to consulting gigs and speaking fees. All of these value-capture mechanisms introduce different sorts of friction. That friction doesn't mean that we shouldn't try to capture value from research, but that it's important to consider the effects of value capture on the research and its impact. I'll dig into each mechanism to show you what I mean.

Patents

Patents only apply to research that directly goes into a product, but there is a lot of work (and failures) by different people and organizations that eventually leads to the patentable research. Bluntly, we stand on the shoulders of too many giants to give them all credit , which makes it impossible for all the people who pave the way for research to get a kickback from patents. Large R&D labs amortize some of this work, but the modern system of startups and academia fractionalizes the work and weights the rewards towards the people at the end of the chain who directly contribute to the final patent or spin out a startup. While weighting the rewards towards end products is great at incentivizing that final grindy push, it disincentivizes targeted piddling around . Consider also that research projects often need to be combined with other research to create something really valuable. The entire point of patents is to create a "toll" on combining intellectual property with other knowledge. As the saying goes, "if you want less of a thing, tax it." While any single licensing fee can be painful but reasonable, combined they can make an invention no longer worthwhile and kill it in the cradle.

Finally, capturing value with a patent can be wildly inefficient. In an ideal situation, someone building a product that incorporates the patented process comes to you, the two of you negotiate a licensing deal, and they send you a check every year. The world is not ideal. Often, you need to find people who are violating your patent and threaten to sue them if they don't pay up. Standard lawyer advice 87 when building something is to not look for prior art because it decreases your liability in case you happen to reinvent something. Even if someone does come to license your patent, the negotiation over licensing terms can be brutal β€” there are no standard terms and especially for a startup it can create a drag chute on a product's profitability that makes an already hard job even harder. Once the licensing agreement is signed, you still need to make sure that the company is paying you the royalties you're due and sue if they're skimping you. Many inventors have spent a lot of their lives in court over patents 88 and some, like Charles Goodyear 89 , wind up dying destitute regardless.

Products

In order to capture research value with a product, the research needs to make a single product 90 better than its alternatives. Unfortunately, products rarely succeed on the quality of their new technology alone. Instead, products are coupled to companies, leading to many other factors that affect the value captured by the researchers besides the research itself, or even the product. Markets, sales channels, margins, fundraising, perception, etc. all make or break companies independent of their products.

Just as it's a long and windy road to a productizable piece of research, it's also a long, windy, and narrow road to successfully productizing that research. Arguably, the work to productize the research is equally or more valuable than the research itself. The unfortunate consequence is that the best technologies don't always win! And even if they do, the value of the research as a fraction of the company's value is often small.

Slight Tangent: Pharmaceuticals are usually figure 1 for "capturing value from research." However, pharmaceuticals are unique in their productizability. It's easy to trace new molecules back to the scientists in the lab and those molecules are patentable. Drugs demand relatively little work to go from research to a product. You don't need to worry about design aesthetics, usability or user personas when taking a drug to market. Scaling, manufacturing, and tweaking are of course hard and should not be ignored. If the drug does what it says there is close to zero market risk β€” people don't like to die. The standardized FDA approval process combined with the Pharma-insurance complex means that there is almost no channel risk either. This is all to say that pharmaceuticals might not be the best exemplar for capturing value from research.

Indirect Value Capture

Researchers can also capture value from their research by consulting with companies who could benefit from that research, getting speaking fees, selling books, and just generally acquiring social status. While in ways this can be good because it encourages people to spread knowledge as far and wide as possible, those same forces also incentivize exaggeration, sensationalization, and at worst, falsification (see: the replication crisis.) Indirect value capture also pushes researchers to try to grab all the credit for themselves. Instead of trying to create a monopoly on the research itself, researchers can capture monopoly rents on research credit.

Is uncapturable value actually valuable?

There's a common implicit (and sometimes explicit) view that if a piece of research doesn't lead to a valuable product or patent then it isn't valuable itself.

Caveat! This entire section is of course, adopting the larger stance that the purpose of research is to be valuable, which isn't true! I'm going to sidestep a bigger discussion of why knowledge and discoveries that will never save single life or create a single dollar of GDP (What does the sex life of snails look like? What happened before the Big Bang? 91 ) are still incredibly important. Instead, I'm going to stay within the restricted framework of "valuable research."

For research to be valuable, it needs to somehow end up in a product. Remember, someone needs to buy manufactured technology eventually in a monetized economy . However, there are many pathways by which research can eventually end up in those products. Some of those pathways might enable researchers to capture value with better value capture mechanisms; I want to argue that the value of other pathways are inherently uncapturable.

There is a lot of research that would make many different products a little bit better, but the improvements aren't worth the overhead of patenting and licensing. At the same time they aren't modular enough to be products on their own. Imagine a manufacturing tweak that saved ten-thousands of companies $100 over several years. Valuable, but not enough to license on either side. You could imagine that situation might be remedied by better value-capture mechanisms. Though given current physical and cultural technology, I am skeptical that the overhead of making the value creation sufficiently legible will dominate and prevent useful value capture. 92

Some impactful research creates solutions to problems where finding the answer is incredibly hard but the solution is shockingly simple once found. This situation applies to a lot of design work and best practices. Arguably you could patent these, but the work to hunt down and sue everybody who used it would require massive resources and perhaps just lead to people taking the hit and not using it in the first place. It's questionable whether better mechanisms could help here, though you could make an argument that in the same way that the iTunes Store drastically decreased piracy, better mechanisms could make it easier to give kickbacks.

We stand on the shoulders of too many giants to give them all credit. Like this sentence, research often follows circuitous routes and sometimes it's not even clear who you're building on or you are separated from them through so much time that it's impossible for them to capture some of the value they create. If you build a product with the help of a fifty-year-old paper, do you give some royalties to the author's heirs? There's also the question of failures: does a research group deserve some of the value if lessons from their failure led to your success? How much? Is it different if they handed you a lab notebook or just told you how important it is to use human oil from the front of your nose to grease a wire See " Tacit Knowledge, Trust, and the Q of Sapphire ." at the bar after a conference?

While it's not strictly uncapturability, there is a significant class of innovations that would create drastically less value for the world if their value had been captured by their creators. There's also just a lot of clearly valuable work that never turns into money. How would even the most sophisticated IP mechanisms have made Norman Borlaug β€” whose agricultural research has arguably saved the lives of over a billion people See " Congressional Tribute to Dr. Norman E. Borlaug Act of 2006." β€” a bajillionaire?

While better value capture mechanisms may help, we also need better social technology to fund and reward research that is truly a public good.

Current value-capture mechanisms are crude

The direct ways to capture the value from research are to patent it or build a product around it (and leverage trade secrets). Other possibilities are more indirect and credit-based: consulting, speaking fees, or leveraging reputation to get more lucrative positions later.

Patents

Patents require an expensive application that can take years to process, lawsuits to enforce, and effort to monitor for violation, and lead to an extremely illiquid market. On top of that, there is tons of valuable work that just isn't patentable.

Capturing value with a patent is often inefficient. In an ideal situation, someone building a product that incorporates the patented process comes to you, the two of you negotiate a licensing deal, and they send you a check every year. The world is not ideal. Often, you need to find people who are violating your patent and threaten to sue them if they don't pay up. Standard lawyer advice when building something is to not look for prior art because it decreases your liability in case you happen to reinvent something. Even if someone does come to license your patent, the negotiation over licensing terms can be brutal β€” there are no standard terms, and especially for a startup, it can create a drag chute on a product's profitability that makes an already hard job even harder. Once the licensing agreement is signed, you still need to make sure that the company is paying you the royalties you're due and sue if they're skimping you. Many inventors have spent a lot of their lives in court over patents, and sometimes wind up dying in the gutter in spite of that.

It's worth noting two historical facts about patents that shed some light on their limitations. Patents have gone from well-reviewed descriptions of already-built mechanical inventions to hastily reviewed descriptions of everything from software to biotech written by lawyers. The number of patents issued in the US has increased by four orders of magnitude since the patent office opened β€” from 33 in 1791 to 354,430 in 2019. 95 The number of patent reviewers hasn't increased anywhere near that much. On top of all of that, patents weren't even created as a value-capture tool for discovery or invention. Instead, patents started as a way for monarchs to increase their income without going through Parliament by granting temporary monopolies. See " Age of Invention: How to Build a State ." Of course, the modern patent system is explicitly meant to incentivize innovation, so this might be nothing more than a historical anecdote.

Additionally, patents inherently prevent a piece of intellectual property from being combined with other knowledge . The combination-preventing nature of patents is particularly problematic if you want to use them to try to fund work to address gaps in work on processes and systems (which naturally require technological combinations).

Products

The first reason products are a crude way to capture value from research is that most modern products are an amalgamation of different technologies and designs. So while a piece of research may have vastly improved a component, that doesn't necessarily translate to a vastly superior product.

Second, products are inherently coupled to companies, so the success of a product (from a value capture standpoint) is inherently tied to the success of a company. This coupling means that there are many other factors that affect the product's success besides the product itself (let alone the research-based piece of it). Markets, sales channels, margins, fundraising, perception, and more all make or break companies independent of their products. "The best technologies don't always win" is an adage for a reason.

"But unique new technology creates a moat that will make the company successful!" Jerry Neumann's " Productive Uncertainty " argues convincingly against pure technology with the idea of "excess value" an invention would produce for a startup.

If a moat exists prior to the startup being founded (say, a patent) then, absent uncertainty, this patent could be sold for at least as much as the startup could garner from it.

More broadly, product-driven value capture forces innovations to be subject to the constraints on startups or corporations. None of this is to say that products are a bad way to capture value, only that they are subject to many constraints and contingent requirements that mean that the correspondence between valuable technologies and technologies whose value can be captured by a product is weak.

Patents inherently prevent a piece of intellectual property from being combined with other knowledge

Imagine a system with components A, B, and C, each of them owned by a different entity. On their own, they are worth one unit but the system is worth 10 units. Arguably, the value of the last unit added to the system is actually eight. A game-theoretical situation occurs where each IP owner holds out to be paid eight units. An alternative situation is that the value of the system is five, but A, B, and C all arbitrarily set their price to be two.

This situation is exacerbated the more different applications there are.

This combinatorial drag from patents is why, in most industries outside of pharma and chemicals, patents are a net drag on innovation. For a much deeper discussion about where patents are helpful or harmful, see The Patent Crisis and How the Courts Can Solve It . Chemicals and drugs usually have a 1:1 correspondence between patents and products. On the other hand, semiconductors and software can have dozens of patents in a single product.

What about a non-exclusive license? A piece of IP under a non-exclusive license becomes something much closer to a public good. Non-exclusive licenses have other problems: They enable you to capture less value and still require lawsuits and monitoring to enforce.

Value capture can hamstring impact

We often talk about individuals or organizations capturing the value that they create . However, conversations about value capture can shift from an instrumental goal in service of encouraging more innovation to an intrinsic goal: that people should be justly rewarded for the value that they create. I want to argue that from a practical perspective, value capture as an intrinsic goal is a chimera, and point out its significant downsides.

Value capture as an intrinsic goal requires that you (or at least a market) can put a price on everything, and that just isn't true. Norman Borlaug arguably saved a billion lives. What is the value of those lives? The people who benefited most from his work were some of the poorest people in the world, so their contribution to GDP is negligible. And yet their lives have value. What is the value of knowledge about how the universe started, or the weird blob fish that live at the bottom of the ocean? One could make an argument that perhaps in the far future our studies of the big bang will lead to warp drives, or the blob fish will lead to a cure for aging. I can't shake the belief that this knowledge is important even without contributing one cent to GDP, and any mechanism to find a "dollar equivalent" would be absurd. Markets are amazing, but they require certain conditions to work. It's not clear that those conditions can be met for everything.

Belief in value capture as an intrinsic goal warps people's focus. If you believe that value capture is an intrinsic goal, it makes sense to focus on value-capture mechanisms without consideration to whether those mechanisms are the most effective way to encourage valuable behavior. Viewing value capture as intrinsically good encourages the stance that if someone or something is unable to capture value, it must not have been valuable in the first place. If you asked, many people don't explicitly believe this, but pay attention and you will see it implicitly worm its way into conversations and logic.

Characterizing creations that would be hamstrung by value capture

Two notes:

  1. By "public," I mean technology that is not illegal to copy without permission. It doesn't necessarily mean it's "open" (though that does make it more public). It also doesn't mean that it was funded by the government (which, incidentally, funds plenty of private inventions).
  2. To avoid introducing a new term I'll be using the term "creation" to describe nebulous discovery/invention/potential innovation-type things. " Heuretic" is a better word , but I've introduced enough new terms as it is.

How can we think about the nebulous line between creations that would be hamstrung by value capture and those accelerated by privatization?

You can approach the question both empirically and theoretically. Both approaches are flawed. Empirically, there are anecdotes to support any position. Theoretically, you can make arguments on both sides and the ultimate conclusion is something around "It depends." I'm going to focus on the theoretical approach to outline the characteristics of creations that would be hamstrung by value capture and lean on the empirical approach to argue that potential innovations that have these characteristics are increasingly common in the world. This section only skims the surface of this topic as far as we need to understand the sorts of technologies that current institutions have trouble enabling. For a much deeper dive, see the already-mentioned-but-worth-mentioning-again The Patent Crisis and How the Courts Can Solve It .

Ignoring incentives and costs, scientific and technological knowledge will have more impact if it is more public. If knowledge is more public and accessible, more people can try more experiments, and more brains will be able to focus on the real problems. The creation of technology is a combinatorial process See The Nature of Technology: What It Is and How It Evolves and " One Process ." , and public knowledge enables more combinations.

That's a big "if." Incentives do exist, and research can be expensive.

So there are good arguments both for holding knowledge private and for making it public. We neither live in a socialist paradise ruled by an omniscient overlord who distributes resources to their optimal use nor a world where frictionless markets exist for everything, distributing value perfectly to its creators. So the answer to "Will a creation have more impact if it's private or public?" is "It depends." Our job is to figure out what makes the answer tip to one side vs. another.

One important question is whether a technology is valuable on its own or in combination with other technologies. And, in the latter case, how many other technologies? Single-molecule drugs are a great example of low-combination technologies, and airplanes are great examples of high-combination technologies. Patents inherently prevent a piece of intellectual property from being combined with other knowledge, so patents will be problematic if the majority of a creation's value will be generated combinatorially. You could think of patents as a tax on including a component technology; taxing a thing is generally a good way to get less of it, all things held equal. If there are only a few big, clearly valuable possible combinations, IP (especially a non-exclusive license) may still be reasonable. Patents" combination-taxing mechanism suggests that "many combinatorial possibilities" may be one heuristic for creations that will have much more impact if they're public.

There is also the question of composability Composability is an excellent and under-discussed concept. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Composability β€” how easy is it to do the combining? How large is a technology's "combinatorial surface area" and how much do you need to mess with its insides to combine it with other things? If a creation has a small surface area and/or is very composable, it can have a lot of impact as a private product. Take bolts, for example. They are only valuable when you combine them with other things to create something new. However, they have a small combinatorial surface area (you almost always use them to hold things against a threaded thing), and you rarely need to modify them (if you do, you're probably doing something wrong, but I have an angle grinder to sell you). Well-designed APIs are also extremely composable. Low-surface-area, composable creations make good private products that can achieve near-maximum impact.

Inverting the characteristics of creations that can create significant impact as private goods is suggestive of the sorts of things that would create significantly less impact if you tried to capture their value: creations that generate uncertain value through combination with many other things, have a large combinatorial surface area, and frequently require internal modifications to enable these combinations to happen.

How common are potentially hamstrung creations?

Even if there's a class of creations whose impact is stifled by trying to capture their value, the question remains: How common are these creations, actually? People trying to capture the value from their creations have generated massive value in the world, so maybe anything else is a corner case. I will argue that they have been common throughout the 20th century, and that increasingly complex technology makes them even more common.

Caveat : There are two glaring problems with this incredibly empirical approach. First, we cannot go through every technology, so there will be inevitable cherry-picking. Second, counterfactuals are hard. There is no way to "prove" that a technology would have had more or less impact if it were public or private. With these problems in mind, the empirical approach is probably most useful to try to disprove the assertion that there is a non-trivial set of heuretics whose impact depends on being public. If the disproof feels weak, that is perhaps the best empirical evidence for the claim.

The innovation ecosystem of the late 19th and early 20th century is one of the strongest pieces of evidence that private innovations alone can carry the torch of progress forward. It was an age of massive technological change β€” Vulcanized rubber! Automobiles! Airplanes! Electricity! Telephones! Almost all created by private for-profit companies, patented, and sold.

However, many of these innovations only hit the mainstream when the component technologies became public knowledge. There was an explosion of car patents in the 1880s and 1890s, and an explosion of car production in the 1900s and 1910s, roughly tracking the end of a patent's 20-year lifespan. It's telling that safety glass was patented in 1905 and became standard car equipment in 1926. Of course, this could be completely correlational, and the time gap between invention and diffusion is just how much time was needed for learning-by-doing to happen.

None of these technologies were complex enough that you couldn't figure out how it works by taking it apart. Nor did they require up-front capital costs inaccessible to individuals without institutional backing. Those attributes mean that, almost by default, the technologies became public knowledge as soon as they were sold. The sufficiently low cost and complexity combined with the cost of acquiring and enforcing patents in multiple countries at once 102 meant that while private, for-profit organizations were creating the technology, the technology itself was effectively public. It was virtually impossible for a single organization to blunt its impact across the whole world.

Many of the "charismatic" In the sense of "charismatic megafauna ." technologies of the late 19th century were "final goods" with relatively small functional surface area. Cars move you and your stuff fast, telephones let you talk to someone else, airplanes move stuff through the air. Even electricity was primarily just used to light stuff up and spin things. Additionally, you could make these technologies good enough to have some market using relatively low-complexity component parts that could be created in-house. In situations where those component parts were private thanks to patents or just secrets, the invention's impact was suppressed until the components became more public. The canonical example is the Wright brothers" patent on coupled wing-warping/rudder control for airplanes, See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wright_brothers_patent_war . which arguably There literally is an academic argument over this. For arguments that patent thickets did stifle airplane development, see " Spillover Effects of Intellectual Property Protection in the Interwar Aircraft Industry ," and for arguments that patents weren't a problem see " The myth of the early aviation patent hold-upβ€”how a US government monopsony commandeered pioneer airplane patents ." I find the former compelling, but it's tricky. stunted the American airplane industry for a decade.

The upshot is that few Industrial Age technologies meet the criteria that we would predict should lead to a technology being hamstrung by being private. Strictly enforced patents on the technologies that approach the criteria (like airplane control) seem to have hamstrung impact in the US, where the patent was in effect.

So which technologies would meet the criteria for being hamstrung by attempted value capture? The age of chemical engineering that began in the early 20th century seems like good hunting ground. Chemicals and the scalable processes to make them are rarely a final product and can be tuned for many different purposes.

The Haberβ€”Bosch Process is one of the most charismatic chemical processes. It also turns out to have been made public through a non-exclusive license at gunpoint. From Enriching the Earth :

The first transfer of the Haber–Bosch process abroad was a result of the Versailles Treaty, which the defeated Germany had to sign in 1919. By its terms, BASF was obliged to license construction of an ammonia plant with an annual capacity of 100,000 t in France.

It would be an entire (worthy!) research project to discern the licensing practices around other chemical processes. However, skimming through the history of the heavy hitters, there seem to be repeated references to multiple companies bringing them to market. See " Not Counting Chemistry: How We Misread the History of 20th-Century Science and Technology." Additionally, a significant chunk of the work still ended up in academic papers instead of patents, whether it was being done in universities or industrial labs. See " The Decline of Science in Corporate R&D " (again). The number of papers that industrial labs published suggests that at least more of the steps leading up to an innovation were public than today.

It's worth noting that before the relationship of government, academia, and technology fundamentally changed in 1980 with the Bayhβ€”Dole Act, it was hard to have exclusive license rights on federally funded research. The situation flipped after 1980 to a world where research institutions by default had exclusive rights to the output of federally funded research. This shift coincides roughly with the distinct absence of new general-purpose physical technologies. Obviously, any direct causal link is speculation at best. At the same time, ignoring it feels dishonest as well. Counterfactuals are hard.

The computer age is littered with anecdotes of technologies that were only impactful because their creators failed to capture their value. Alan Kay argues that the technologies created in Xerox PARC have created trillions of dollars in value. See this interview with Alan Kay . Imagine a world where Xerox sued the living daylights out of any product that used a mouse or a GUI. I suspect the mouse and GUI would have been much less impactful in that world.

Counterfactually, what would have happened if AT&T were not required to license for free all of the non-telephone patents at Bell Labs? Two plausible scenarios could have happened: Either AT&T would have had a monopoly on the semiconductor market or William Shockley would have had an exclusive license to the technology. In the former situation, it's likely that semiconductors would have been treated the same way that most technologies tangential to a core line of business historically have been: marginalized and deprived of the chance to live up to its promise. An eternally expensive piece of military equipment. If instead Shockley negotiated an exclusive license with AT&T, consider that Shockley was a notoriously terrible manager, and Shockley Semiconductor went out of business in 1968. The traitorous eight would never have left to found Fairchild, so Shockley Semiconductor might have persisted, but would the innovations that came out of Fairchild have happened? Would Hoerni's Planar Process have been created and adopted in either situation? Poor management is great at killing weird paradigm-shifting ideas. The entire modern technological stack might never have existed.

Linux is literally powering Mars Rovers now. How much irreplaceable impact has it had? If Linus Torvald were trying to capture the value it created, how would Linux have been anything other than an inferior version of Windows?

Conclusion

Many ideas have massive impact because people can copy them without paying their creators. Any mechanism for capturing value has more or less built-in friction. This friction can limit the diffusion of innovations.

The strong argument in favor of trying to capture value is that value capture is what incentivizes and funds innovations in the first place. Value capture is not a binary "either you capture all of the value or none of it," but a question of how much of it you capture and how you capture it. Arguably, Google (and many other companies) has created much more value than they have captured and may have created less value if its creators hadn't tried to capture that value. Profit really is important! However, these companies generally are not generating profit from innovations with large surface area that generate uncertain a priori value through not-particularly-modular mechanisms.

Current value capture-mechanisms are crude . It's possible that better value-capture mechanisms could create a world where any innovation could create as much value as possible and its creators could be rewarded. However, it doesn't seem possible to capture value (especially in non-digital technologies) without introducing some friction into the system in order to track contributions and forcibly extract money from people who are keeping more than their fair share. 109

Finally, the potentially hamstrung class of innovations seems to become more prevalent as the complexity of technology increases and technological development depends more and more on long research pipelines. Given all of these considerations, it seems clear that navigating between impact and value capture is a Scylla and Charybdis situation indeed. Like other unavoidable tensions, there's no "correct" answer beyond "Constantly pay attention and course-correct!"

For fun, I will leave you with a potentially controversial 2x2 of innovations that would arguably have had more or less impact if they were public or private.

Legal structure is critical to institutional capacity

While we didn't mention them directly, legal structures were lurking just below the surface throughout the discussion of profit and value capture. Who exactly is capturing value and how profit incentivizes individuals is all a matter of legal structure. Many people implicitly or explicitly believe that legal structures are akin to "syntactic sugar" in programming: a surface-level feature that ultimately has little effect on organizational outcomes. I want to argue that instead, legal structures are intimately tied to organizational capacity.

When you boil it down, legal structures are contracts that establish how money and explicit power flow in an organization. Served that way, how can legal structures not be tightly coupled to organizational capacity? The government acts as an external forcing function on these contracts: allowing some, disallowing others, and using them to assess one of the two inevitabilities of life (taxes) which actually play a big role in what people decide to do with their money. Taxes often play a big role in incentives for people and organizations with enough money to make a difference with their money.

Historically, new legal structures have enabled new classes of activity. The creation of joint stock companies in the 1600s enabled larger and riskier private ventures like the East India Company See " A Brief History of the Corporate Form and Why It Matters ." and arguably enabled a lot of English settlement in North America. The creation of limited liability corporations in the mid 19th century helped enable the railroad boom first in Britain and then in the US. See The Modern Corporation and Private Property . In 2020, SPACs made going public a reasonable move for several non-software technology companies that may not have happened otherwise.

Entrepreneur First is a great example of an organization using unconventional structures to unlock new strategic moves and outcomes. They are in part an investment firm, but their cohorts require much more operating capital (for example, more employees) than the traditional VC firm structure provides. So, in addition to the normal-for-VCs closed-end funds with LPs, EF also has a C-corp that issues equity and has its own investors that both employs most of the people at EF and "co-invests" with the closed-end fund. This unconventional structure allows EF to be more operationally intensive than a normal VC fund and has the added side effect that if their investments are successful enough, it's conceivable that they could choose to stop needing LPs at all. Eventually, the organization could become an autocatalyzing cycle where operations are funded solely through liquidated investments held by the C-corp. Y Combinator has a similar structure and uses this additional flexibility to do experiments like the now-defunct YC Research . This additional long-term operating flexibility wouldn't be possible in a normal VC fund structure because most VC firms fund operations off of their management fees and return all their profits to LPs. I want to make it clear that there are trade-offs so this is not a strictly-better structure for all tech investors. But it is a better structure for EF and YC to the extent that they conceivably could not do what they do without it.

So if new legal structures have a large impact on organizational capabilities, why shouldn't organizations trying to do qualitatively different things take legal structures seriously? Clearly there are many organizations that have accomplished great new things without innovating on legal structures. This is yet another place where counterfactuals are hard. We do more than speculate on organizations that structural constraints caused to never exist in the first place. Other organizations may have been subtly forced into more mainstream behavior. However, the historical precedent and surprising number of ways you can be creative with legal structures suggests that, at least on the margin, there is a lot of room for new legal structures to enable new organizational capacities.

Legal structures affect where you can get money and what you can do with it. Even the words we use have both a funding and an organizational meaning. "Nonprofit" both implies that funding is from people who don't expect a return on profit and is a specific designation under the law. Similarly, "selling equity" implies a specific legal structure and also that funding will come with a certain set of expectations.

How money works in an organization spills over into organizational incentives in too many subtle ways to list. For example, creating equity enables you to raise money that doesn't need to be returned on a finite time scale (which can incentivize longer-term thinking) but puts ownership of a fraction of the organization in the hands of outside shareholders (who can push for different decisions than the founders would have made 112 ). If you want to avoid someone else owning your organization but still want to raise money from outside investors, you could organize as an LLC, but then you start a ticking clock to return that money with interest. Nonprofit status enables you to raise money that people can write off on their taxes and don't expect a return on, but it comes with a host of requirements around what you can and must spend money on. These examples are only meant to illustratively scratch the surface β€” someone should really write The Big Book of Organizational Incentives .

As an example of the coupling, let's think through funding a DARPA-riff.It is hard to capture value from research, so a reasonable first instinct is to look to philanthropic funding. Philanthropic funding pushes an organization to legally be a nonprofit both because people expect a tax break for money they give away and because "nonprofit" signals, "No, seriously, we're not going to use your money to get rich." 113 That's not the end of the story, though, because from the perspective of pure impact the best move will likely be for a startup to carry some of the technology forward. It would be extremely helpful to use some of the startup's eventual profit both to fund further work at the DARPA-riff and to tap into for-profit investment. People are willing to write much bigger checks if they think they'll get a return on them! However, the standard nonprofit structure puts many constraints on your ability to issue equity (which would be the normal structural way to channel for-profit investment) ...

The traditional nonprofit structure is a bad idea for an organization that requires a significant chunk of capital and produces uncertain results on a long time scale

A nonprofit can be organized as either a charity or a foundation. Each has different constraints, but in both cases, nonprofit structures are more at the whims of the entities giving them money than they would be if they were providing a good or service. It just comes down to leverage.

Legally designated charities enable donors to write off their donations as tax-deductible. However, charities need to get 33% of their income from donations and those donations need to come from "small donors" who each provide less than 2% of their total funding. Because of these rules, charities raise money on a yearly or sub-yearly basis, which forces them to give people a reason to donate on that short timescale. Uncertain results on a long timescale don't lend themselves to the sorts of updates that encourage people to give on short time scales. "Hey, uh, still doing that experiment that we were doing last time we asked you for money." The short funding time scale also means that cash flows can be quite volatile, which poses obvious problems for long-term research. You can't really fire a researcher and then hire them back a year later when funding conditions get better.

Legally designated foundations don't have a charity's requirements for regular small donations, so they are not as susceptible to the whims of a large group of people. Instead of regular small donations, foundations need to convince a few donors to give a lot of money. Big checks always come with strings attached. While the check size might be higher, it's often distributed over time, so an unhappy donor can pull out, leaving the organization in the lurch. These donors also get lower tax write-offs, which can give a feeling of more ownership over the organization and thus more control over its direction. So while the constraints on foundations are different from those on charities, they still need to keep donors happy, which could push the organization toward shorter-term, sexier projects that align with philanthropists" priorities.

Admittedly, I've outlined worst-case scenarios for how incentives can play out in both charities and foundations. However, people always spend money for a purpose. In the case of philanthropy, that purpose is a complex, fragile "product" (as opposed to more simple products, like eggplants or index funds). Taste in projects is more flighty than the desire for return on capital. People usually want closer involvement when the money is buying a more ill-defined good than "more money."

It's easy for a philanthropy to take actions that do not deliver on donors" expectations. In other words, it's easy for philanthropies to become misaligned with their money factories. This easy misalignment makes it dicey to rely only on donations for long-term projects. Unfortunately, the nature of research means that it both needs stable, long-term funding and often fails to live up to expectations. In short, structural constraints make the traditional nonprofit structure a shaky foundation for an organization that requires a significant chunk of capital and produces uncertain results on a long time scale.

Disclaimer: I am not a lawyer.

You'll notice that most organizations" legal structures don't stray too far from a few basic models. New companies tend to be vanilla C-corps if they intend to sell equity and LLCs if not (and their equivalents outside the US). Organizations with charitable intent tend to be 501(c)(3)-designated charities or foundations. VC firms tend to be LLCs with a few members forming a general partnership. This general partnership then creates closed-end funds that are limited partnerships with other investors.

The structure of a typical VC firm. From " VC Funds 101: Understanding Venture Fund Structures, Team Compensation, Fund Metrics and Reporting" by Ahmad Takatkah

At the end of the day, legal structures are "just" contracts that determine how money flows and how decisions are made both within and between one or more taxable entities. We generally think of organizations in terms of these tax designations: LLC, c-Corp, 501(c)(3), etc. 115 Our custom of using tax designation as one of the primary descriptions of an organization hints at the fact that taxes matter a lot! Tax designations can place requirements on organizational structures like the need for a board of directors and determine both what happens to money that comes in (for example, C-corps and their shareholders are both taxed; only the shareholders of an LLC are taxed) and what an organization is allowed to spend money on (501(c)(3)s can only spend money related to their official missions).

These contracts have a big impact on an organization's output. That impact makes it important to find the appropriate legal structure. Moreover, legal structures have more flexibility than most people assume.

People tend to implicitly treat legal structures like elements and particle physics 116 β€” a set of clear options in the same way that hydrogen, helium, and carbon are composed of electrons, protons, and neutrons. That's not the case at all. You can actually write whatever contract all the involved parties are willing to agree to. The question is what will happen afterward β€” it could be totally fine, or the government could sue you out of existence and send you to jail. It seems like, given a set of laws, you should be able to tell what is in bounds and what is out of bounds. In reality, it's extremely hard for lawyers to know a priori whether a legal structure is legit without trying it and seeing whether you get sued. There are no first principles that let you derive legitimate legal structures. 117 Composite materials are a good analogy: Beyond well-studied or simple examples, it's extremely hard to predict how truly novel materials will perform.

This illegibility is an underlying reason why people tend to stick with legal structures that have already been safely demonstrated. (The same is true with materials!) Limited partnerships are used for almost every small investment firm not because it was a carefully thought-out structure but because it had precedent in the whaling industry, where it had basically been made up by common law. Delaware C-corps are everywhere in part because they have so much case law behind them that the lines of acceptability are much clearer than any other option.

Sticking to well-known structures creates several reenforcing feedback loops. Most lawyers are hesitant to even suggest a non-standard structure because they don't have the experience to intuit the affordances of a new structure. That leads to even fewer lawyers with that experience. People are (rationally!) hesitant to fund non-standard structures. It's generally not worth the work to avoid the risk of a lawsuit, surprisingly high taxes, or other surprises. This pressure from backers to stick to standard structures creates an adverse selection effect: The things people are interested in funding are nudged toward traditional structures, leaving only the things nobody wants to fund with weird structures and making it a good guess that most organizations using non-standard structures are sketchy. The association between unconventional legal structures and sketchy organizations wears the habit grooves even deeper, increasing hesitation to do something different and creating more examples of organizations that have succeeded despite few-sizes-fit-all legal structures. This survivorship bias ignores all the counterfactual organizations that failed or never even started because of the restrictions they faced. 118

This all might seem like cute esoterica, but the combined flexibility and illegibility of legal structures has several significant consequences. Legal structures are intimately tied to the question of how money works in an organization, the actions that an organization can take, and the incentives they can deploy. Don't we want more organizations that can use philanthropic dollars to produce public goods, but then are able to capture some of the value they create in order to produce more things? Or perhaps organizations that look like a company but, instead of implicitly lasting forever, they have finite lifetimes like a closed-end fund?

OpenAI's capped-profit/nonprofit structure See https://openai.com/blog/openai-lp/ . is a great example of an organization playing with legal structures to match their own situation and shape incentives in ways that wouldn't otherwise be possible. They need to be able to pay AI researchers top dollar, while at the same time their nominal mission is to keep powerful AI technology from being captured by organizations whose incentives are to use it to maximize shareholder value. 120

At the same time, doing things differently for the sake of doing things differently is rarely a good idea. It's well worth paying attention to Chesterton's Fence. Most of the time, it is easier to use standard legal structures, especially considering the cost of lawyers who understand contract and tax law well enough to play with soft constraints. Old legal structures rarely provide huge barriers to an organization's ability to achieve its goals, just inconveniences. It's a situation where continuous changes can lead to discrete differences β€” will the little inconveniences from standard structures eventually cause an organization's death (or derailment) by a thousand cuts?

For a DARPA-riff, I would argue the answer is yes.

Part II: It is Worthwhile and Possible to Riff on ARPA - The Layout of the Maze

Why try to emulate DARPA and not Bell Labs

Bell Labs was a product of its time and a set of unique conditions that no longer exist today. DARPA, on the other hand, seems able to work in today's world just fine. Its biggest hamper is perhaps the constraints that come along with being part of the government.

I suspect there is more room to play with the DARPA model because the "search space" for replicating Bell Labs is both more restricted and has been heavily explored. Bell Labs didn't have a unique model. While they definitely have the best narrative, there were several other great industrial labs. Many organizations have tried to create "the next Bell Labs." Those that have tried it as a part of an existing company without the right external conditions were crushed under the constraints of modern corporate R&D, and those that tried to do it as a separate entity did not address the trifecta of conditions required by healthy industrial labs . Arguably, we still do have great industrial labs today, just not in atom-based disciplines .

In contrast to Bell Labs clones, extragovernmental riffs on the DARPA model are rare. Many organizations give lip service to the DARPA model but don't resemble it at all. It's easy to set out to build a DARPA but end up building a Skunkworks. Of the organizations that do seem like earnest riffs, Actuate (solutions R&D for social good) and Wellcome Leap (solutions R&D for health) have only started in earnest in the past year, so it's hard to say much about them. Ink & Switch seems to be successfully riffing off the DARPA model in the software world. There is a lot of organizational white space still to explore.

At the same time, this apparent whitespace could be the same as shouting "The real nongovernmental DARPA model has never been tried!" into a graveyard of failed attempts. Maybe there have been organizations riffing on DARPA that died quietly or didn't explicitly draw the connection between their model and DARPA's. Another real possibility is that the DARPA model just doesn't work outside the context of the government. However, the evidence suggests that a private DARPA-riff is not impossible, and may in fact be possible. After reading this section, hopefully you'll agree.

In summary, it seems possible to replicate DARPA in today's world, but it doesn't seem possible to purposefully re-create the conditions that enabled Bell Labs to be what it was.

There are DARPA-style ideas that DARPA doesn't pursue

A key reason why it would be impossible to riff on DARPA is because actual DARPA is already tackling all the parts of the adjacent possible that fit within its structural constraints. All DARPA programs need to tie into US defense priorities. However, almost any piece of technology can be tied into defense priorities somehow. For example: Human-computer interfaces are for command and control, medicine is for helping wounded soldiers and disabled veterans, improved learning techniques can help train military personnel, new materials and energy-generation technology can be deployed on the battlefield and make our military more energy-secure, and fundamental physics could enable warp-drive-powered battlecruisers!

Therefore, it's quite reasonable to conclude that DARPA would already have tried any potentially impactful DARPA-style program. If this were true, trying to run similar programs with less resources and clout would be idiotic.

Luckily, evidence suggests this isn't the case. It's perhaps a cheap analogy, but assuming that DARPA will undertake every potentially awesome technology program is the same line of thinking as assuming that Google will go after any potentially valuable software product.

One piece of evidence is simply testimony from former PMs that they had program ideas rejected because they were insufficiently applicable in a defense setting. It would be lovely to have a list of "good ideas DARPA rejected," but DARPA is still a part of the US Department of Defense so it's hard to just ask about those proposals directly. 121

Another piece of evidence are stories of how many of the programs eked into existence by the skin of their teeth. Their stories often involve a dedicated PM doggedly arguing for them through several rejections or impending budget cuts. See, for example, the history of DARPA's drone program in The DARPA Model for Transformative Technologies: Perspectives on the US Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency . It could be that DARPA's selection process is actually amazing at supporting almost every eventually-viable idea but puts them all through the wringer first. This seems unlikely. Instead, if many of the DARPA programs, especially those that are especially exciting outside of the military, barely made it over a line, there are as many or more that didn't make it over that line.

While DARPA famously has fewer constraints than other government agencies, it's still part of the US government bureaucracy. As such, DARPA still has a number of constraints that could rule out otherwise viable programs. DARPA doesn't do any research in house, so it cannot pursue programs that would require spinning up an entirely new organization. It still needs to use government procurement, hiring, and salary practices, all of which could sabotage potential programs.

At the end of the day, though, the only hard evidence to support the claim that there are DARPA-style ideas that DARPA doesn't pursue is to successfully design and run them!

Can the DARPA model exist outside of the government?

In addition to establishing the fact that it is possible to riff on the DARPA model, it's also important to ask whether that riff can exist outside of a government. Is it only possible to riff on the DARPA model successfully with organizations like IARPA or the recently announced British ARPA, ARIA? See " A new UK research funding agency ."

There is no good way to satisfyingly answer the question, but we may be able to make more headway on the isomorphic question:

What are the reasons that something could only exist in the context of a government?

Put differently, there are "hard" and "soft" reasons why an organization would need to be part of the government. Hard reasons are reasons that you literally cannot get around without a government. Soft reasons are places where it seems really hard without a government but possible. If the only reasons we can find are soft, we are forced to conclude that a DARPA-riff can exist outside of a government.

There are two hard reasons that an innovation organization needs to be part of a government. The first is that the organization's core work involves controlled technology, like things that can directly be turned into nuclear or bioweapons. In these cases, if you aren't part of a government, some government will, with varying degrees of force, make sure that you don't exist at all. 124 The second hard reason an organization would need to be part of a government is when it requires more capital than could possibly be aggregated without the power of a nation-state. The original moon landings are good examples of work that could not be accomplished without government funding 125 β€” NASA's budget was 4% of the US federal budget in 1965 and 1966.

All of the other reasons feel soft. There are probably more soft reasons why an innovation organization would want to be part of the government than are useful to enumerate. I'll list a few.

  • The work involves doing things that impinge on people's rights (privacy, property, etc.).
  • The work is expensive without much possibility for capturing a return.
  • The work creates public goods or outputs whose value can only be captured on the scale of a nation-state.
  • The weight of government authority could significantly advance the work.
  • The organization needs a recurring budget that it can't find as part of a corporation.
  • The organization needs to utilize equipment and resources owned by the government, like national labs.

An organization riffing on the DARPA model absolutely is subject to several (all?) of the soft reasons. However, I would argue that it isn't subject to either of the hard reasons. We have actual DARPA to do weapons research, and the numbers necessary to run actual DARPA are large ($3.6B in FY2020), but not impossible to achieve without government funds.

While being part of a government could certainly relax some constraints standing in the way of success, it imposes many other constraints. Successfully riffing on DARPA might be extremely hard without being a government entity but riffing on DARPA is extremely hard as a government entity β€” just in a different way. Two actions of former DARPA directors Regina Dugan and Arati Prabhakar seem to back up this conclusion β€” both of them are working on nongovernmental ARPA riffs. Dugan is the head of Wellcome Leap and Prabhakar started Actuate . I agree with their tacit conclusion, and would argue that in addition to being viable without government support, 21^st^-century riffs on DARPA should be private.

21st-century DARPA-riffs should be private

On the back of evidence that it's possible to build a DARPA-riff outside of a government, I want to make a more aggressive claim: 21st-century DARPA riffs not only can but should be voluntary organizations. There are two major reasons for this. First, modern bureaucracies introduce an intractable tension between accountability and the opacity a high-variance organization needs to succeed. Second, government independence gives an organization a fighting chance to do better than (actual) DARPA in some areas by taking advantage of the ability to do things that a government organization cannot.

If you ask most people "Do you want the government to be accountable for the money it spends?" They would probably answer, "Of course!" In a liberal democracy, the government is nominally accountable to The People; as much as possible, we demand transparency and oversight over how our money is spent. Government transparency is good, but it also stands in direct opposition to the fact that, arguably, opacity is important to DARPA's outlier success. See " Why Does DARPA Work ?" If we are painfully honest, the actions that lead to great results often a priori look like bad ideas or offend our sense of fairness. It is completely reasonable to demand that an elected government be fair. However, making a game more fair reduces its variance and rules out many activities; the way ARPA operated in the '60s would never be allowed now. These two conflicting but correct outlooks put any government organization trying to produce high-variance results between a rock and a hard place. The way to slice through this Gordian knot is by not forcing the government into the position in the first place.

DARPA isn't perfect. See the " Room for Improvement" section of "Why Does DARPA Work? " While some of the downsides, like high-variance outcomes, are structurally tied to the model itself, others are artifacts of being a government organization. As a government organization, DARPA needs to have an air of impartiality β€” they must issue open calls for most programs, go through a rigorous process to demonstrate that they considered all options before making a decision, work with legitimate institutions, show they are paying no more or less than fair market price, the list goes on. On paper, these are all good things, but they also create a slower, more constrained process that potentially leaves opportunities for a private organization. A private organization could potentially tap talent that is hard for a government organization to attract because it has much more flexibility to play with salaries, equity, and other incentives. Hopefully, this list (which could be expanded) is convincing evidence that there are potential improvements to the DARPA model that are out of reach for government organizations.

Things any DARPA-riff will need to consider

A DARPA-riff both can and must do multiple experiments at once

Running multiple organizational experiments flies in the face of the common wisdom that you should only change one thing at a time. 128 This is absolutely true for building a successful business. However, people have tried millions of fairly open 129 experiments with organizational practices over many decades in everything from human resources to management and employee compensation. As a result, while you might not like how an organization does HR or design, basic organizational structure and best business practices are pretty effective. Research organizations have simultaneously had many fewer experiments (just compare the number of companies that have been started to the number of university labs that have been started), less selective pressure, and looser feedback loops.

Concretely, you're in a bind if you simultaneously believe it is worthwhile and possible to riff on DARPA and that you should only change one thing at a time. You would be limited to creating new government organizations, like ARPA-E and IARPA. If you buy the argument that it's possible to riff on the DARPA model outside of government, that single shift forces you to rethink multiple things (legal structures and funding, for a start), whether you like it or not. At that point, clinging to existing structures could become more of a liability than wisdom, because the assumptions that made those structures good ideas in the first place no longer hold.

Setting up a new colony in Massachusetts is very different than setting one up on Mars in terms of the number of things you'll need to rethink. Environmentally, Massachusetts is pretty similar to England, so it makes sense to keep many things the same. Sure, you might want to use some different crops to deal with the weather, but you still want to use roughly the same tools, farm the same way, and build houses the same way. Even the extreme religious stuff that was the whole point of the colony eventually reverted to the mean. Mars, on the other hand, is unlike anywhere on Earth (except maybe Antarctica). If you try to live there in anything resembling the way you did before, you're dead.

So a DARPA-riff needs to do some institutional experiments to survive at all. On top of that, there are a number of experiments that seem like they can only be done in the context of an organization. Since the goal of a DARPA-riff is not just to enable more paradigm-shifting technology but to try to demonstrate a new institutional model, guinea pigging should be part of its role. A laboratory for experiments in 21^st^-century research management, if you will.

This isn't to advocate for throwing everything away just because it smells like the past. Chesterton's Fence is important! Instead, it's important to learn from those who have come before β€” hopefully, the valuable lessons from Bell Labs and DARPA have convinced you of that. But in a strongly disequilibrium state, you need to evaluate each component on its own merit, and perhaps grab components from disparate parts of history or the organizational landscape.

Pulling off this balance will be like sailing between Scylla and Charybdis; extraneous experiments on one side and the same old incentives leading to the same old outcomes on the other. With this gauntlet before us, I want to note that there is a whole ontology of both experiments and structural components that shouldn't be poked. There are some parts of the DARPA model that, if changed, would make it hard to even call an organization a "DARPA-riff" in the first place. On top of these immutable considerations, there are some experiments that must happen. Figuring out how money works without a DoD budget is one of the most glaring ones. Other experiments are more "optional" β€” they might make the difference between success and failure, or they might be a distraction.

A DARPA-riff needs to be obsessed with program managers

The relationship between the DARPA model and empowered program managers is like the relationship between a hydra and its many heads. The heads are part of the hydra, its business end, and one of its defining characteristics.

" Why Does DARPA Work? " covers DARPA PMs extensively, but the key points are worth reiterating both as a refresher and to emphasize that empowered PMs are the core thing one should not mess with. "What about managing programs through a committee?" NO. "What if performers just submitted grants and coordinated among themselves?" NO. "What about a more rigorous approval process to make sure money isn't wasted?" NO. "What if people could be career program managers?" NO. You get the point.

The importance of program managers means that anybody attempting to replicate DARPA's outlier results needs to be utterly obsessed with bringing the right program managers on board. Getting the right program managers will require understanding both who those people are and how to convince them to join.

Program managers can't just be general high-quality people but need to exhibit specific traits: curiosity, low ego, good at bringing people together, good at communication, and have high doing-to-talking ratios.

A DARPA-riff will need to do some hard work to convince good program managers to join. A new organization can't depend on accumulated prestige, and a private organization can't take advantage of patriotic instincts the way that a government organization can. So you'll need to be creative! One speculative approach for recruiting PMs is to embrace people who have expertise but are not traditionally credentialed. This pattern is not uncommon in software-adjacent disciplines like deep learning or cryptography, where people can independently build mastery and then do real cutting-edge work without going through traditional institutions. Outside of software, uncredentialed research expertise is rarer; developing it requires more specialized equipment and tacit knowledge that lives primarily in traditional institutions. However, uncredentialed expertise still exists outside of software, and if predictions about the democratization of disciplines like biology play out, they may become easier to find over time. Developing taste in uncredentialed experts might yield fruit!

A DARPA-riff has career affordances that you can't find elsewhere, which will hopefully appeal to a subset of folks who would be excellent PMs. There aren't many opportunities to work with extreme autonomy on getting a technology out into the world without needing to tune the work to either produce papers or hockey-stick growth numbers. I suspect that there are a few extremely competent people out there (it doesn't take that many) who are seething to shift technological paradigms and are willing to trade off salary, prestige, and stability for the ability to make those shifts happen. Of course, often that sort of pitch leads to bitter disappointment, so smart people are rightly skeptical of it! The burden of proof is then on the organization to become a place that does deliver on those promises.

More than any specific ideas, though, a DARPA-riff will need to constantly ask itself: How do we become a place that PMs want to work?

People who have done research should be in charge of research (and more generally, people who have done a thing should be in charge of that thing)

Once hired, PMs have significant agency to make programs succeed or fail. This power should make anybody building a DARPA-riff take very seriously the questions, "What makes people good at being in charge of research and how do you find those people?" This question is also important for anybody who cares about innovation systems more generally β€” too-involved funders, MBAs running the details of research programs, and other control-project mismatches are all too common.

"Being in charge of a thing" is a nebulous concept. However, at its core is the ability to directly control the fate of that thing; some combination of deciding whether a project or person gets approval funding, how well a project is doing, and coming up with ideas for what should be done in the first place.

In research especially, there are very few metrics you can use to distinguish between a good idea and a bad idea or how a project is progressing once it's started. Even when metrics suggest that "everything is working great!" it is easy for researchers to fool themselves, optimize for the wrong thing, or overlook a core problem. As a result, the decisions that someone in charge of research needs to make demand a level of understanding that can peel back the metrics and poke at what's going on underneath.

The "understanding" that allows you to see past metrics has a lot to do with intuiting the affordances of that thing. That is, you have built up a rich enough tapestry of patterns that you can subconsciously integrate many explicit and implicit inputs and have a sense of the effect of different interventions into the system. This process, almost by definition, is hard to abstract β€” if we were good at de-abstracting it, you could put it in a metric!

To illustrate, I'll use an example that has nothing to do with research: gym managers. You can always tell when the manager on duty at a gym is a weightlifter themselves by how they react to people deadlifting in socks. Deadlifting in socks is a common practice; nominally because it enables you to "feel" the floor as well as possible and balance while lifting heavy weight (and also because some famous weightlifters recommended it many years ago). Rules that everybody must wear shoes in the gym are also common practice; shoes can mitigate the damage if you drop something heavy on your foot, and some people would find it gross if everybody were walking around without shoes. 130 If a manager hasn't done much lifting, they'll immediately stop someone deadlifting in socks β€” it's against the rules! (Note here that metrics are nothing but rules about what's good and bad.) If a manager has lifting experience, they'll generally let someone deadlift in socks if they look like they know what they're doing and are lifting enough weight to warrant it. Not only will they probably not hurt themselves, but shoes won't stop damage above a certain weight, anyway. Note even in this simple example how quickly we run into illegibility! What does it mean for someone to "look like they know what they're doing"? It's not just a matter of how big their muscles are or whether they use chalk β€” it's how they put the weight on the bar, how they hold themselves, the intention in their eyes; that is, things that are completely inadmissible as metrics. Research is immensely more complex than a gym!

This person looks like they know what they're doing.

As uncomfortable as it is to say in our metrics-driven world, both good gym managers and research managers depend on intuition. This section should more accurately be titled "People who have an intuition for research should be in charge of research." However, it's extremely hard to get a sense of someone's intuition for a thing β€” even if you yourself have intuition for the thing. So, in a delightful meta-situation, we need to find more legible heuristics for "intuition."

"Having done a thing" is a reasonable heuristic for "has intuition about this thing." It's of course not always true; people who have done a thing do not always have intuition for it, and people who have not done the thing can sometimes build intuition for it! It helps if they have a track record that could only be accomplished by having an intuition for the thing or extreme luck. Of course, it requires intuition to distill what pieces of a track record can be accomplished without intuition. Intuition turtles all the way down.

The "gotcha!" comes in deciding what counts as "having done the thing." Does someone who worked in a biology lab doing experiments on rat brains count as someone who has "done" biology? Should they be in charge of a molecular genetics project? A DNA-origami project? This is where you need to defer back to the fact that experience is just a heuristic and attempt to tease out how much intuition is shared between the past experience and the future work. The trap to avoid here is that sometimes someone will overspecialize and end up being less qualified to be in charge of a thing in an area that's normally quite close to their experience. For example, someone who is a tenured professor in biology working on lipid bilayers might be terrible at being in charge of a CRISPR-based program, while someone with relatively less experience would be good at it. The trap there is to take that logic to the extreme and declare, "Experience doesn't matter!" If you take anything away from this section, I hope it's that experience does matter, but that it isn't the only thing that matters.

Of course, at some point, someone needs to be in charge of several things and they can't have done everything. My hunch is that the trick to navigating this unavoidable tension is "attenuated delegation." That is, the less intuition someone has, the more heavily they should delegate; or, conversely, the less they should be involved. You could roughly divide involvement into three levels: binary go/no-go decisions, progress measurement and course correction, and directly helping in the process. Each of these requires quite a bit more intuition than the one before it.

Anybody attempting to emulate DARPA needs to be willing to sit with a lot of discomfort for a long time

The results of solutions R&D take a long time to impact the world. On top of that, the attribution is usually mixed because of how many entities often need to touch a technology between where a DARPA-riff will work on it and when it enters regular use. I desperately want to burn this into your brain because I suspect a DARPA-riff's most likely failure mode is the frustration of some combination of people working on it or supporting it, leading to result-killing timescale compression or abandoning the organization altogether.

The Mother of All Demos happened in 1968 β€” six years after J. C. R. Licklider joined DARPA. Personal computing technology took another five years to go from this demo to prototype system in the Xerox Alto and (depending on how you count) another 10 years after that to become a commercial product in the Apple Lisa. That's 21 years between the start of the ARPA program and a product on the shelf that people could buy. Similarly, the first DARPA Grand Challenge that arguably kicked off modern autonomous driving happened in 2004 (and was arguably a failure β€” none of the cars could complete the course) and, of this writing in 2021, autonomous vehicles are still not mainstream. That's 17 years and counting.

People in the startup world often pride themselves on their timescales β€” 10 years is the rough average from first funding to IPO. The timescales we're looking at here are twice that or more, not to an IPO but to a customer-facing product (if the work even ends up as a product!) that's possibly attributed to someone else entirely. It's like running a relay marathon. Of course, some scientists are rolling their eyes β€” "That's nothing," they say, tuning the experiment they've been working on for the past three decades.

Adding to the uncertainty is the fact that a big part of solutions R&D is to get the ball rolling, not to get it to the goal. This role is important but muddles attribution. You see this historically in how DARPA seeded some of the best CS departments in the country; DARPA doesn't get credit for everything that has come out of the University of Utah CS department The University of Utah CS department is notorious for early computer graphics work like the Utah Teapot . Pixar Founder Ed Catmull is a direct descendent of this tradition. (nor, arguably, should it!). DARPA money often plays a role of de-risking research to the point that the NSF is willing to fund it. Almost by design, there will be arguments about who deserves credit for things a DARPA-riff helped with.

On top of excruciating timelines and attribution uncertainty, riffing on DARPA will entail working on weird shit . You've heard of the successes, but DARPA regularly funds wacky things that go nowhere. Things that make you think, "They're wasting my tax dollars on that?" Warp drives. Remote-control insects. Creating fusion through soundwaves. Super-soldier serum. Though it should be noted that DARPA had nothing to do with telepathic goat murder research. Over time, DARPA directors have needed to fight to keep DARPA from being toned down and turned into a normal R&D org.

A big part of the unavoidable discomfort for supporters of a good DARPA-riff is that any of these attributes can also be used as an excuse for poor performance. "We're not showing clear results because we need more time to resolve uncertainty" can be true or false, and even the person saying it might not know the difference. The line between a program that just takes time and is going nowhere is often illegible to everybody but the people working on it. Ditto for attribution and weirdness. Here lies yet another Scylla and Charybdis that we must navigate; there is no compass here besides trust.

It is important for big things to start small

As far as I can tell, every big thing that really sticks in people's heads started at bare minimum an order of magnitude smaller than where it ended up. This goes for companies, organizations, projects, movements, you name it.

By contrast, it seems that whenever someone starts something huge β€” a massive fund; a company that is hyped from day one; a movement where they declare, "We are starting a movement to change the world!"; a new field where they declare, "We are creating a new field!" β€” it ultimately disappoints.

There are several practical reasons for why big things tend to succeed more often if they start small. Three of the biggest ones (which are not completely independent of each other) are expectations, momentum, and trust.

When something starts small, it has the ability to exceed expectations. Exceeding expectations sticks in people's heads more than meeting them. Exceeding even small expectations is memorable! By contrast, when something starts big, it has massive expectations from the beginning, so it is hard to exceed them.

Small things have less momentum, which in turn allows you to make many quick micro-adjustments to iron out problems and move in a better direction. Less momentum lowers the cost of changing things. It's the difference between being in a kayak and a cruise ship moving at the same speed. If you know you're going in the right direction, you want to be in the cruise ship, but almost nobody gets everything right from day one. You want to turn the low-momentum kayak into the cruise ship only once you've made several course corrections.

The momentum-related costs of changing direction come in several forms. Direction-changing costs could appear as coordination-related transaction costs between people: The more people who are involved in something, the more coordination costs you accrue when you try to change anything. The costs could be in terms of reputation: The more eyes and expectations on what you're doing, the bigger the confusion and/or reputation damage you cause when you choose to do something different. The costs could be literal capital costs: If you buy an expensive piece of hardware that ends up being useless or a large office in a place that ends up being the incorrect place.

Starting small enables you to build up trust. In large part, building trust is a process of verifying that someone or something is both competent and reliable. To some extent, it's just about "getting in the reps." The same quick, small actions you use to course-correct can (if done competently) create many trust-verify loops. A history of reliable and competent small actions provides a strong foundation for bigger leaps of faith. On the other hand, asking people to take a big leap of faith up front often leads to second-guessing or sandbagging, which in turn can bring even the largest organization to its knees.

In the context of a DARPA-riff, this is a warning about the dangers of coming out of the gate yelling, "We're going to change the world!" and raising a massive war chest commensurate with that statement without first working out kinks and building trust. It's not an injunction against massive ambition! Soberingly, the admonition to start small creates a tension in conjunction with the "portfolio" nature of the DARPA model, which we'll address later.

The boon and bane of institutional missions

On the note of ambitions, it's worth briefly talking about institutional missions.

Institutional missions are a tricky thing. On the one hand, they can be an inspirational rallying point and a powerful filter for actions you should and should not take. On the other hand, they can be distracting piles of words that obscure reality and enable people to feel good about themselves without earning it.

It's unclear whether people focus too much on missions or too little. Most mission statements are bullshit on which people fixate at the expense of putting their heads down and letting actions speak for themselves. This phenomena encourages (at least in me) a counter-reaction to eschew thinking and talking about mission entirely β€” "Let's earn the luxury of thinking about mission through hard work first." I'm still sympathetic to this view, but at the same time, spending some cycles on missions is probably worthwhile. People use an institutional missions as proxies for what that an organization actually does, so without a mission it will be hard to succinctly get across a useful mental model of an organization. It's especially hard to build that model if you're doing something new with long feedback loops, like building a DARPA-riff. All institutions have implicit missions, so there is a mission, whether you make it explicit or not.

A good mission can also be a powerful filter both on actions and on people. You should be able to ask of any action or project, "Does this fit within the mission?" and be able to come up with a concrete answer that can plausibly be no. Creating a mission that sounds good to everybody is seductive β€” we all want to be loved and be lovely. As a result, most missions are so nebulous as to arguably cover anything. They don't enable you to rule things out . Any given mission shouldn't appeal to everybody. Institutions need to differentiate between individuals inside and outside themselves, and missions that don't sound good to everybody can help with that.

SpaceX and Bell Labs" missions are good examples of broad but discriminating missions. Bell Labs" mission was to "Support the Bell System with Science and Engineering Advances." SpaceX's mission is to "Make humanity an interplanetary species." Both of them cover a massive range of activity, but at the same time, there are many activities that do not fit under their umbrellas. Both of them will appeal to some people and completely turn off other people.

Frontier technology has bespoke sales channels

Outside of software and therapeutics, there are no good default paths for new technologies to get into the hands of end users. 132 The less it looks like anything that came before it, the fewer precedents there are for how to buy or sell it! Figuring out how to sell a technology 133 can be a comparable challenge to developing it in the first place. It's a challenge that's worth worrying about even if your primary goal is not to make money, because someone needs to buy manufactured technology eventually in a monetized economy . Questions about sales channels introduce a tension into technology creation β€” things you can do to make a technology more useful to end users (for example, which performance metrics you focus on), but too much focus on end use can push the technology into a premature local optimum.

By contrast, software and therapeutics have well-established sales channels. As the two (glaring) exceptions to the rule, they are illustrative and perhaps hint at how to improve sales channels for other technologies. People have sold software for long enough and in enough volume that there are well-established strategies for diffusing software: "land and expand," enterprise sales, open source while selling managed instances, etc. Individual consumers and companies have reasonable mental models about how to acquire and test new software. This isn't to say that everything has been tried, that software sales is easy, or that software is all the same. However, there are fewer unknown unknowns on both sides of a software transaction than, say, a new sort of hydrogen filter for a petroleum-processing plant.

The FDA approval process provides a set of extremely legible milestones that allow therapeutic developers and funders to resolve the normal standoff: "We'll tell you how much money we'll give you if you can tell us some clear milestones." "We'll be able to tell you some clear milestones if you give us a sense of how much money you'll give us." Instead, the negotiation becomes, "We need $X to get through Phase 1 β€” if we do that, will you agree to give us $Y to get through Phase 2?" "Sure." 134 This relatively straightforward (but still risky!) path from lab to market depends on the incredibly low market risk for therapeutics that make it through the FDA. Insurance companies pay for the majority of therapeutics and regularly agree to how much they will buy and how much they will pay for a given therapeutic, assuming it makes it through the approval process. A big part of the job for more traditional VCs who focus on therapeutics is to lubricate this whole process.

Figuring out how to sell a technology can be as complicated as creating it in the first place: Who/which member of an organization is actually spending the money? Who do you need to convince that it's a good idea? How do they know it works? What does the contract look like? Do you need to go through a third party? All of these questions slither subtle tentacles back to the development process. These tentacles raise many uncomfortable questions: How low does the bill of materials need to be? What does this need to interface with? Should this even be a product? ("Build a startup" is in itself a channel design choice.) Uncertainty about a technology's sales channel in turn affects how much support it can get in the first place. People are far more willing to support uncertain work like pharmaceutical development that has a clear light at the end of the tunnel.

People creating technology often do not have the bandwidth to give sales channels the attention they require. This limited bandwidth creates another tension: What is the role of the people building technology in diffusing 135 it? On the one hand, the idea of "build technology and throw it over the wall" has serious flaws β€” small nudges in development can have large effects on its usability, and involved creators can be essential to successful diffusion. On the other hand, imposing diffusion-related questions at the wrong time can be distracting at best, and at worst force a technology to a local optimum where it is "useful" but blocked from reaching its full potential.

It's tempting to punt on worrying about the challenges of diffusing new technology until it's actually built. The instinct is reasonable but misguided because (un)certainty about diffusion feeds back and hinders or helps technological development. Drugs with billion-dollar development bills can be created only because therapeutics have well-established sales channels. There's a feedback loop between the availability of funding and what gets built! 80% of VC dollars go toward software and pharma See the NVCA 2017 Yearbook . which invariably leads to more work in those areas, further establishing sales channels and reducing uncertainty in future software and pharma investments. Conversely, the sentiment "Even if it works, you have no idea how you're going to sell it (or otherwise enable it to have an impact)" makes people hesitant to fund development work or put in the effort to get the technology to work in the first place!

I am not confident about any of the many possible experiments a DARPA-riff can do to address the sales channel dilemma, so I'll describe them further on in the "Speculation" section. However, I am confident that any DARPA-riff that wants to have an impact needs to address the dilemma somehow.

Stepping into the shoes of industrial labs

If we've established anything so far, it's that a DARPA-riff will need to fill at least part of the niche once filled by industrial labs . Embracing that role, it's important to ask: Which aspects of the niche is a DARPA-riff well suited to fill? Where will it be weak? What can it do structurally to maximize strengths and minimize weaknesses?

1. Industrial labs enabled work on general-purpose technology before it's specialized.

Working on general-purpose technology will require a DARPA-riff to explicitly and uncomfortably push back against the (accurate) common startup wisdom to "focus on a niche." 137 At the same time, any technology does need to find an initial niche eventually, so programs should have some precise hypotheses about an eventual application. Counterintuitively, this tension between considering how a technology will be used and potential local-optimum traps may be one of the barometers for a healthy organization, ensuring that it doesn't lean too far one way or another. Maintaining this unstable balance will require a lot of work to frame goals correctly. It's perhaps a cliche at this point, but the development of the transistor is a good example of walking the general-specific line. It had a precise goal β€” to find a solid-state replacement for the vacuum tube that we think will be useful in telephone repeaters and switches β€” but nobody constrained the work to only make more efficient repeaters and switches.

2. Industrial labs enabled targeted piddling around.

A DARPA-riff can enable targeted piddling around through low-stakes seedling programs, using a single organizational umbrella to quickly spin up and close down programs, and having some number of "free radicals.'

DARPA uses low-stakes seedling programs to "acid test" the riskiest part of a program idea. See the section " DARPA uses low-stakes seedling programs to "acid test" the riskiest part of a program idea " of "Why Does DARPA Work?" There's no reason that a DARPA-riff can't shamelessly copy that strategy directly. The trick is to go into them with the explicit attitude of "Let's see what will happen." It's important to acknowledge that while everyone would rather seedlings lead to a promising program than be nothingburgers, reality might have different plans. The way to prevent that preference from morphing into pressure is to explicitly make sure that negative results don't have lasting effects. Specifically, negative results absolutely cannot affect a program manager's ability to run other experiments or affect an external researcher's relationship with the organization as a whole. 139

It's tempting to ask, "Why do you need a DARPA-like organization at all? Just run each program separately." An organizational umbrella over programs can turn targeted piddling around into a compounding long-term benefit. 140 The results of piddling around often come in the form of informative failures or tacit knowledge. It's easy for these results of piddling around to evaporate. If each program were a separate organization, pursuing any serendipitous discovery that didn't help the program move toward its goals would be a distraction. Someone might keep track of those discoveries, but there would be relatively little incentive to do so. 141 An umbrella structure can enable serendipitous potential side quests discovered during the main body of a program to be fed back to the beginning of the "pipeline" and possibly become their own programs.

A DARPA-riff could also enable targeted piddling around by explicitly having people whose job is to piddle around! These "free radicals" In chemistry, free radicals are atoms, molecules, or ions with an unpaired valence electron that makes them extremely reactive. ) could be competent individuals who aren't attached to any specific project. They could help PMs design programs, do experiments, or research areas that nobody in the organization has even thought about. You could imagine this role as having the flavor of a "pre-PM [X]-in-residence." The role would resemble an internship in the sense that the radical isn't doing anything mission-critical and could potentially become a PM, but without the expectation of that outcome. The role would be unlike an internship because it would involve much more independence, and there would be less of a teaching component β€” people in the role would already be skilled. It also rhymes with the constant theme in Bell Labs narratives where "free radicals" between projects would play a critical role in everything from semiconductor manufacturing techniques to solar cells. See The Idea Factory again. However, this sort of role would need to be defended: It's anathema to efficiency and could easily be a waste of resources!

3. Industrial labs enabled high-collaboration research work among larger and more diverse groups of people than in academia or startups.

A DARPA-riff can be a bridge between different worlds and disciplines. Seedling programs enable PMs to slowly pull together a diverse set of performers by holding regular closed-door meetings (so people can talk about real problems instead of just showing off good results) and making sure different performers know one another. See the section " A large part of a DARPA program manager's job is focused network building " from "Why Does DARPA Work?" J. C. R. Licklider was a master of this β€” not only having regular meetings for PIs working on different aspects of interactive computing but for the graduate students working on it as well. A DARPA-riff can further enhance these collaborations if it explicitly pulls people together into a single organization as the program progresses.

Interactions between program managers could create a high-collaboration environment between wildly different disciplines. Program managers can and should be drawn from a wide range of professional and technical experience. This diversity, combined with correctly set cultural expectations, could go a long way toward filling this aspect of the niche. For example, at Bell Labs, "They were not to work with their doors closed. They were not to refuse help to a colleague, regardless of his rank or department, when it might be necessary." From The Idea Factory again.

Realistically, a DARPA-riff won't be able to fulfill this role as well as a golden-age industrial lab. Programs that initially revolve around externalized research might make high-collaboration environments challenging, and there won't be the same number of "floating" people. However, a DARPA-riff will fill this part of the niche much better than academia or startups do today.

4. Industrial labs enabled smooth transitions of technologies between different readiness levels β€” they cared about both novelty and scale.

This one is tricky. If DARPA's small size is indeed a key to its success, a DARPA-riff can't act like an industrial lab by supporting both a large number of people working on extremely speculative projects and a large manufacturing team.

A scheme where programs are set up so that they can bud off into their own organizations could address the problem by becoming the organization on the other end of the handoff. As they progress, programs could shift from loose collections of projects to independent organizations whose purpose is to get the technology that they developed out into the world, either by selling it as a startup or helping people adopt it as a nonprofit.

Of course, many technologies are more effective if they're absorbed by existing organizations; this is especially true for new processes. See " Fundamental Manufacturing Process Innovation Changes the World ." Another important approach to the handoff problem will be involving organizations that the technology might be handed off to from day one (or before!).

For a small DARPA-riff, smooth transitions will require long-term relationships 147 with both exploratory researchers and manufacturers. Ideally, these relationships could become part of a relatively systematized pipeline 148 reminiscent of Flagship Pioneering, with less profit-focus and more discipline diversity. On one end of the pipeline, you want people helping you surface and smoothly build programs around promising research. On the other end, you want to have trusted connections who can help "manufacture" the output, whatever that entails. How to build this pipeline is an open question. While it will inevitably involve a lot of legwork, it could be systematized by creating a consortium of partners similar to the MIT Media Lab or the Santa Fe Institute.

5. Industrial labs provided a default customer for process improvements and default scale for products.

This part of the niche is strongly coupled to the previous one, and comes with similar possibilities and challenges. Smooth technology transitions at the end of a program basically demand something resembling default customers and scale. A DARPA-riff will never have its own Western Electric. However, a persistent organization with a track record of quality work can get into a situation where every program doesn't need to start from scratch when it is ready to "graduate.'

6. Industrial labs often provided a precise set of problems and feedback loops about whether solutions actually solved those problems.

This is a part of the niche that a DARPA-riff can absolutely move into, but it will require a good chunk of conscious experimentation. Feedback loops that generate precise problems and filter solutions are not structurally built into a DARPA-riff. At the same time, other prerogatives around graduating programs can serve double duty. Additionally, like many independent research organizations, DARPA-riffs could do consulting work to help external organizations implement new tools and processes. In addition to generating feedback, this sort of consulting could nudge larger organizations toward being customers (see #5 above) and provide an alternative revenue source. As mentioned earlier, a DARPA-riff could also set up a consortium similar to the MIT Media Lab, which would give the organization a default reason to talk to other organizations. A consistent stream of new PMs with diverse sets of industry experiences could create another feedback loop.

7. Industrial labs provided a first-class alternative to academia where people could still participate in the scientific enterprise.

This one is tough. A single DARPA-riff might be able to offer an alternative to academia for some people, some of the time, but it won't be able to change the ecosystem. However, we could dream very big and imagine that an alternative could emerge from an ecosystem of DARPA-riffs and other new types of research organizations. 149 A DARPA-riff's programs will most likely still lean heavily on academic work, especially early in its life. As a result, it won't do as well at providing an alternative to academia as industrial labs. You could and should also support other alternatives to academia by working with extra-academic researchers instead of using academic affiliations as a proxy for competence.

8. Industrial labs enabled continuous work on projects over 6+ year time scales.

One might expect that it would be hard to support long-term projects in a DARPA-riff because PMs with relatively short tours of duty are a core part of the model. However, DARPA has a strong precedent of programs outlasting the tenure of the PMs who started them. There's no reason a DARPA-riff couldn't do the same thing. Arguably, PM-PM handoffs can maintain continuity better than many academic labs, where most of the work is done by grad students with 5–6-year tenures who sometimes have little incentive for smooth handoffs, 150 or startups, where employees are notoriously mercenary and it can be surprising if someone stays more than three years.

However, it's also important to consider constraints that the organization will face early in its life that will hopefully relax over time. While a DARPA-riff is structurally set up to tackle long-term projects, it's probably not a good idea for the first projects to take 6+ years to show results. The reality of the situation is that a new organization will have no track record, so people will (rationally) have less patience with it. Organizational reputation matters. If funders, potential employees, and collaborators start to see the organization as unable to get things done, 151 it can become a self-fulfilling prophecy.

9. Corporate labs enabled work in Pasteur's Quadrant .

There's not much to say here. This is the tightrope that a DARPA-riff should try to walk: things that are too researchy for a startup and too engineering-heavy for academia.

A DARPA-riff will need to invert the normal relationship between an innovation org and its money factory

Research orgs are typically subsidiary to their money factories. Bell Labs was subsidiary to AT&T, PARC to Xerox, DARPA to the DoD and Congress, academic labs to grant givers, etc. This relationship generates so many of the incentives that run counter to producing high-quality and eventually-impactful research. A lot of the specific friction can be traced back to mismatched Buxton Indexes β€” the length of the period over which an entity makes its plans. The Buxton Index comes from E.W.Dijkstra in " The Strengths of the Academic Enterprise." Research just has a longer time signature than the natural beats of elected officials, quarterly earnings, or LP fundraising rounds.

What if you invert this relationship? Instead of the revenue-generating entity (money factory) being the "parent" org, the innovation org becomes the parent.

First, it's worth asking what the distinction between a parent and a child or subsidiary organization means. Ultimately, it's about power β€” whose priorities take precedence? In the most extreme sense, if there is a choice between an action that will destroy one organization or another, which one gets priority? It's uncomfortable to talk about inter-organizational power in the same way that it's uncomfortable to talk about what will actually get you fired or promoted in an organization. 153 This power usually takes the form of contracts if the children are external to the parent, and budgets if they are internal. To some extent, the power is simply a function of which organization came first. If a parent organization could survive before its child came along, it's a clear proof point that it can survive without the child. 154

It's tempting to say, "Ah, yes! Inverting the relationship between innovation orgs and money factories will solve the problems!" But that is magical thinking. Inverting the relationship won't solve the mismatched Buxton Indices; it will just change which side exerts power. That relationship will create a different set of constraints on what happens and what can exist. The inversion is rare enough that there aren't many case studies, but one could imagine projects never shipping because of perfectionist thinking or a hesitance to kill projects that aren't going anywhere.

It feels slightly nonsensical not to have the main profit-generating entity as the parent organization because otherwise, where does operating capital come from before the money factories are created? Let's call this the "bootstrapping problem." The challenge becomes finding a transient source of money that simultaneously puts few enough constraints on the organization that it can do the work to create cash-generating children while at the same time not warping its incentives toward generating cash-children as soon as possible at all costs.

There are examples of organizations that have pulled off the inversion with varying degrees of success. Flagship Pioneering, Ink & Switch, Idealab, and TandemLaunch are all both the parent organization and the innovation organization, while the companies that they spin out are the money factories. If you squint, Howard Hughes Medical Institute also fits this pattern β€” its funding comes from its foundation, which is the subsidiary organization. HHMI is especially noteworthy because unlike the others, its survival isn't contingent on spinning out companies. As we've noted, spinning out companies is a double-edged sword. On the one hand, companies are a powerful technology diffusion mechanism, but on the other hand, there is a significant class of innovations that would create drastically less value for the world if their value had been captured by their creators.

How did each of these organizations address the bootstrapping problem? Flagship Pioneering, Idealab, TandemLaunch and their ilk β€” "researchy startup studios" β€” are explicitly out to create high-growth, venture-backable startups. This goal allows them to bootstrap with for-profit investment capital. It also incentivizes them toward projects that can become high-growth startups on a short time scale. Ink & Switch has bootstrapped with a combination of sources β€” investment, "friendly investment," 155 and consulting with companies on the implementation of different areas of their research. Howard Hughes Medical Institute cheated by starting already sitting on top of a massive endowment. The upshot is that there isn't a well-worn path for an innovation organization to get to a point where its operating capital can consistently come from subsidiary organizations if it wants to work on things that might not want to become high-growth startups. Charting different possible approaches to the bootstrapping problem is the focus of the next section.

How does money work in a DARPA-riff?

Research is expensive. DARPA's 2020 budget was $3.6B. See " Department of Defense Fiscal Year (FY) 2020 Budget Estimates ." In the long run, a DARPA-riff that works on atom-based technologies is going to need a lot of money. How money works is a major force that shapes incentives and organizational capability, so it is worth taking very seriously.

When considering the pros and cons of funding sources, it's important to think about them in terms of how much they could potentially blow the organization off of its "ideal" course of action. This isn't to say "money taints everything!" It is to say that money comes from people external to the organization who have their own agendas. (Otherwise they would just be part of the organization!) 157

This section explores both the many-forked possibility path for making money as well as the meta-considerations surrounding it.

Could DARPA have a positive return?

Spoiler alert: I suspect the answer is no, given any currently existing value-capture mechanism.

Profit is important for both practical and ideological reasons. One of the most important reasons is that profit enables institutions to be self-sustaining. In steady state, could an organization riffing on DARPA sustain itself, or would it constantly need external money?

It's not an unreasonable question β€” technology eventually needs to be commercialized and diffused in order to actually impact people's lives, which means that eventually it will end up as products on the market . However, it's entirely possible for the product to be so many steps removed from the people who created the original technology that you can barely see the connection, let alone propagate value back to the technology's creators .

One way to get a handle on the question of whether a DARPA-riff could be self-sustaining would be to ask, "Would (actual) DARPA have had a positive return?"

Answering this question is tricky. DARPA doesn't do any research in house, so all research they fund was ultimately done by another organization. Externalized research has a sparse paper trail and doesn't have an obvious value-capture mechanism. Even if DARPA were able to directly capture value from its programs, those programs may have the impact they did because DARPA didn't try to capture their value. On top of all of that, valuable things that can be traced back to DARPA-funded work are usually combined with a lot of other work. This research admixture means that even if you could track down every dollar of sales associated with DARPA research and assume that DARPA would have been able to capture some of it, a fixed percentage of that amount is a terrible assumption.

Given these hurdles, a more tractable question is, "How much monetary value has DARPA spent and created?" Even answering this question is hard β€” DARPA is rarely the first or last organization to touch a project, and on top of that, it's unclear how much their help contributed. Given an accounting of created value, we could then play around with, "Given different scenarios, how much of that created value could have been "captured," and what would the effects have been?"

The numbers I'm going to throw out are sketchy back-of-the envelope calculations β€” in reality, a rigorous accounting of DARPA's full-scale output is a full research project. I'm surprised the government hasn't commissioned such a project, but I've searched high and low to no avail.

DARPA's cost is straightforward. DARPA's budget in 2020 was $(2020)3.6B. Their budget has been roughly stable since its founding β€” except for a massive initial spike because it was originally responsible for what would eventually become NASA and various missile programs. Assuming a constant budget, DARPA has cost $(2021)221B over their 63-year history.

DARPA's output is complicated. The simple place to start is with the stock market: Which companies on the S&P 500 owe their existence to DARPA technology, and how much are they worth? You can see the list and associated calculations here . The total comes out to approximately $(2021)11,200B 158 β€” two orders of magnitude bigger than DARPA's entire cost. Obviously, DARPA isn't responsible for anywhere near all of that value, but it's also unclear what percentage to use. YCombinator's (sketchily estimated) 1.7% ownership at Doordash's IPO See "Running the Numbers on Y Combinator's Best Year Yet ." is a hand-wavy anchor point. Despite ultimate responsibility for a lot of core technology, let's be conservative and say DARPA is "owns" an order of magnitude less at 0.2%. This would come out to a DARPA ownership of $22.5B β€” an order of magnitude less than the total amount that was spent on DARPA. This is surprising!

Of course, this calculation is a massive underestimate: It's only counting public companies, it's ignoring any dividends that they may have paid out, it gives DARPA a tiny ownership, and I'm being very sloppy about what's attributable to DARPA. At the same time, I'm skeptical that private companies (there are many highly valued autonomous car companies especially) or dividends would make much of a difference or that DARPA would own much more, especially given existing value-capture mechanisms. I don't have strong evidence, but I strongly suspect this $22.5B number isn't anywhere representative of the amount of value DARPA has created. The reality may truly be that most of the value that DARPA has created isn't easily measurable. How much modern activity, joy, and wonder is enabled by GPS and the internet? What has been built on top of obscure research funded by DARPA? How many careers has it touched? The trick is that if you can't measure value, you certainly can't capture it.

It is hard for a DARPA-riff to capture value without hamstringing impact

If a DARPA-riff wants to maximize its impact, there are three reasons why trying to capture value is likely a bad move.

First, there are several ways that profit-maximizing organizational structures can hamstring technologies whose impact depends on them . It would be nigh-impossible to avoid impact-killing pitfalls while still capturing value.

Second, the market in for-profit organizations is fairly efficient. The traditional barriers to starting companies β€” initial costs, talent, and long term capital β€” have come crashing down. Software, global supply chains, cloud labs, and the ability to rent lab space + equipment has significantly decreased the cost of starting even atom-based businesses. 160 Silicon Valley reverence has gone global so the people who have what it takes to start a startup both have the information and sanction to do it. There are more early-stage VCs than ever before and the sexy success of SpaceX and other "hard tech" companies means that anything that looks vaguely like it might become hugely profitable can get funded. In fact, the barriers to creating for-profit organizations might be so low that people are starting companies when they shouldn't be. An efficient market in for-profit organizations means that the most impactful work will be unprofitable.

Finally, and perhaps most importantly, many important innovations that are bad investments. One of the most impactful things a DARPA-riff can do is to support projects in this category.

Apart from these broader points, DARPA does specific things that seem effective and worth emulating but at the same make value capture harder.

Externalized research is a load-bearing component of the DARPA model See the section " DARPA doesn't do ay research in house " from "Why Does DARPA Work?" because it enables minimal full-time staff, spinning up or spinning down projects quickly, access rare talents and machines, and tying different approaches in parallel. However, not only is it hard to capture value from research , it is especially hard to capture value from externalized research!

The role of DARPA as a in-between organization See " Rethinking the role of the state in technology development: DARPA and the case for embedded network governance points ." that acts as glue for a broader innovation ecosystem feels weirdly important. That role also plays awkwardly with value capture. If the whole goal is to kick off a community 163 , many entities need to feel like they can capture value from an innovation and might feel threatened or hesitate to collaborate with a purely for-profit venture.

Is there a minimum effective budget to generate outlier results?

It is important for big things to start small β€” many attempts to replicate DARPA's results start too big. See the section " Most DARPA clones start too big or with heavy process " from "Why Does DARPA Work?" So it makes sense to ask: Is there a minimum effective budget to generate outlier results? Can you start with a tenth of DARPA's budget? A hundredth? A thousandth?

There are two lower-budget bounds that you'll run into: the number of programs you need to run to get a single "successful" program and the budget per program for it to have a viable shot at that success.

A back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests that if each program generously has a 10% chance of success (DARPA has a 5–10% program success rate) See " DARPAβ€”Enabling Technical Innovation ." then you need to run at least seven programs to give yourself a 50% chance of at least one program being successful. See this numbers appendix . Whether these programs are run in series or in parallel depends on available funding. However, if it takes five years to run a full program, running them in series could take a decade or more (assuming several unsuccessful programs are terminated early) to even demonstrate organizational feasibility. And this isn't "10 years to a $1B IPO" β€” it's "10 years to getting a really promising technology out into the world that given another decade might produce a measurable impact." Given the absurd timeline of running programs in series, running several programs in parallel is important. The necessity of both starting small and running several programs in parallel to even demonstrate feasibility is one of the core tensions inherent in riffing on DARPA.

The question of minimum program budgets is tricky. Let's first look at some comparison numbers. In the years 2018–2020, among DARPA programs not focused on assembly and production, the minimum budget was $2M, the maximum budget was $31.4M, and the average budget was $12M. See " Department of Defense Fiscal Year (FY) 2020 Budget Estimates " and in spreadsheet form here . The ARPA IPTO directorate that midwifed the personal computer started with a budget of $(2020)47M in 1962. See " ARPA Does Windows: The Defense Underpinning of the PC Revolution ." ARPA-E vacillates around $200–300M/year and has about 50 programs running at any time, which comes out to roughly $4β€”6M per program. IARPA's budget is classified. Could a program go below a couple million dollars a year and still be effective? There are arguments both ways. On the one hand, you could argue that surely bureaucratic inefficiency is pushing those budgets higher than they need to be. On the other hand, it might be that the sort of work that it is most valuable for a DARPA-riff to do needs a relatively large budget, otherwise it would happen in other institutions. Without strong reasons to believe otherwise (which we don't have), it seems irresponsible to assume that you could run impactful programs for significantly less than DARPA. The saving grace is that programs don't need to start at full budget but can ramp up over a year or two.

So is there a minimum effective budget to generate outlier results? Absolutely. The number depends heavily on how often you expect programs to fail and the type of work those programs will entail. There are different strategies you could use to both accept the reality of a minimum effective budget and at the same time start as small as possible to avoid money poisoning. In Part III, I'll argue that (one) feasible approach is a combination of explicit evolutionary forms and tranches.

Income

DARPA-riffs need free cash flow. You need money to pay people, rent lab space, purchase equipment and reagents, hire lawyers to keep regulators from shutting you down, and possibly pay to rebuild anything that you blow up in the process. Figuring out where this money comes from is a narrow path between the Scylla of external constraints and the Charybdis of organizational death. Hew too far toward any established funding source and the constraints it imposes won't let you do anything different from a normal startup, nonprofit, consulting firm, etc. Hew too far the other way and all that freedom will be worthless because you'll need to shut down the organization. The rocks of history are littered with the smashed wrecks of organizations that failed to run this gauntlet β€” Magic Leap is a prime example of the former and Willow Garage of the latter. There are many others, but to avoid disparagement, I'll leave you with a pregnant silence.

Three big considerations for any income stream are whether it is a transient source that could be used by the organization in its early days or could provide steady state income, what order of magnitude you could expect it to provide (Thousands? Tens of thousands?), and how replicable it is. The last point is worth considering because ideally DARPA-riffs would become a replicable institutional model.

This section will walk through potential directions at the many-forking juncture that asks "Where does free cash flow for an DARPA-riff come from?" Or in other words, what are the different tools a DARPA-riff can use to build its money factory ?

Technology licensing

Licensing fees from patents are a straightforward way to make money for an organization that creates technology. Licensing patents lets you focus on creating the technology rather than commercializing it. Licensing also enables you to create an organization that can generate income from outputs that wouldn't necessarily make good startups β€” processes or technologies that benefit from the existing manufacturing, expertise, and supply chains of large organizations.

A few organizations make a significant chunk of money from licensing revenue. Between 2008 and 2012, IBM made over $1B/year in licensing revenue. See " If Patents Are So Valuable Why Does IBM's Intellectual Property Revenue Continue to Decline." Intellectual Ventures' primary business model revolves around licensing. Universities are another example. From a 2015 article on licensing revenues :

Northwestern University topped the income list, at $360 million, a number that was boosted by the sale of its remaining royalty rights to a compound used to control neuropathic pain that is marketed as Lyrica. Other big earners in the survey included New York University, $215 million; Princeton, $142 million; Columbia, $115 million; the UC system and Stanford, each about $108 million; and the University of Texas system, $49 million.

All of these examples do some good research work! However, there are some flies in the ointment. The majority of university licensing income is from drug licensing deals. Both IBM and universities spend far more on research than they make in licensing revenue. Most technology transfer offices are not profitable. See " Benchmarking of Technology Transfer Offices and What It Means for Developing Countries ." All the universities in Canada combined only do $62M in licensing revenue. See " Canada needs a national overhaul of university IP policies." And the steps Intellectual Ventures needs to take in order to get paid have earned them a rather unpleasant reputation.

At the end of the day, patents need to be enforced through the law. The only way to do that is through lawsuits. Ideally people will proactively pay licensing fees, but often they do not, either through maliciousness or negligence. As a result, any organization depending on patent licensing fees needs to also have a staff of (expensive) lawyers constantly monitoring for patent violations and ready to sue to enforce patent rights. This unfortunate necessity is why Intellectual Ventures is maligned as a patent troll. It might be possible to decrease violations by using non-exclusive licenses. However, non-exclusive licenses are usually worth much less than exclusive licenses, even counting the fees from multiple licensees.

Heavy dependence on licensing fees tends to warp incentives. IBM's internal status game is on publishing patents β€” people are promoted based on the number of patents they file rather than getting anything to work. Patents as an accomplishment metric leads to projects being abandoned once they get to a patentable state. I've experienced this personally at other organizations as well.

Licensing obsession also leads to a conflict of interest between researchers and the organization. If a researcher thinks they're on to something valuable, they're incentivized to keep it secret, leave the organization, and set up their own venture to capitalize on the thing they've created without paying licensing fees. Such a surreptitious course of action is totally rational β€” licensing fees are a deadweight loss on any organization that has to pay them, especially a startup. This effect seems especially likely to happen if some or all of the research is externalized.

On top of the organizational problems that a licensing-fee-based income strategy can introduce, patents add a lot of friction to innovation. There are examples throughout history of patents keeping systems that depend on multiple patents held by different entities from being built. Aviation is arguably one of the most notorious examples. Patents hamstring the entire class of innovations that would create drastically less value for the world if their value had been captured by their creators.

This isn't to say that a DARPA-riff should never patent anything. However, it would need to be on a case-by-case basis and have a strong reason why the patent would be in service to the technology. For example, a good reason to license would be to enable a technology to raise further financing where otherwise it could not. The upshot is that while patents could be a way to spuriously create income, licensing is a bad primary income strategy for a DARPA-riff.

Spin-off companies

Another obvious way for an organization creating technology to make money is by spinning off startups to commercialize that technology, investing in them, and using the revenues from liquidity events like acquisitions or IPOs to fund operations.

One might think the prevalence of startup studios is a strong proof point in favor of the spin-off. However, most startup studios (rationally) focus on company ideas with low technical risk β€” well-trodden software paths, direct-to-consumer models, etc. There are, of course, notable exceptions β€” Idealab , Flagship Pioneering , Deep Science Ventures, and TandemLaunch For more on Deep Science Ventures and TandemLaunch, respectively, see Episodes 19 and 30 of the "Idea Machines" podcast. , to name a few. Each of these organizations does take on significant technical risk, but the need to create and capture venture-scale returns limits the sorts of work they can do. In the vast majority of cases, research-y startup studios are constrained to work on classes of problems that have clear-cut sales channels and product pipelines, like pharmaceuticals (and other medical technology), software, or electronics. They also primarily focus on work that has been de-risked by a single academic lab.

An income stream based on spinning off companies has a number of advantages. As anybody who has even heard the words "Silicon Valley" knows all too well, equity in high-growth startups can have truly massive upside. The money from a single successful spin-off can fund many others. Spin-offs could also help align incentives. If a program manager could potentially become a CEO of a company, a DARPA-riff could possibly avoid situations where smart, talented people say, "That sounds good, but I could make much more going off and starting a startup." Another advantage of spin-offs is that in the long run, research affects the world in one of two ways: knowledge or products and processes. Companies are entities whose incentive is (to a large part) to diffuse products or processes as far and wide as possible. So if you're creating new technology that you want to get out into the world (as opposed to sitting on a shelf), creating a company around it is probably a good idea ... eventually.

At the same time, spin-off-based revenue introduces a number of constraints. The biggest is the danger that if every program is aimed at becoming a company, the organization will be incentivized away from things that would create drastically less value for the world if you try to capture their value. Focusing on spin-offs could potentially warp incentives to work on things that could produce short-term wins and things that would be able to raise money easily once they've spun out; spin-outs will probably only succeed if they can raise follow-on capital and turn into income only when they liquidate, so fundable, shorter-term wins are a more predictable income stream.

Using spin-offs as a primary income source also creates a liquidity problem. Even if you avoid all the incentive problems and manage to do maximally important work that could also become valuable companies, given the state of private and public markets, those companies probably won't generate a return for many years. In that situation, you need to get operating capital from outside sources β€” presumably equity investors. These investors will want their own above-market returns, which will apply pressure that can propagate all the way back and warp which programs you undertake in the first place. Pressure from the same sorts of investors who invest in VC funds will create the same pressure that those funds are under. Even with understanding, long-term investors, there would need to be a justification of how any program could become a company. But there are some pieces of a future that maximizes human capability and wonder that might just not make good companies!

Case study: Intellectual Ventures

Intellectual Ventures (IV) has a unique structure that combines income from technology licensing and spin-offs.

Three of IV's four divisions (Invention Science Fund, Intellectual Ventures Lab, and Deep Science Fund) are focused on creating internal patents and spin-offs. So far, the companies they've created have raised $700M in venture funding, See https://www.intellectualventures.com/spinouts . which roughly puts their total value between $5–10B. Assuming IV did not take an equity share too large to dissuade investors (\<20%, perhaps?), that would put their share at $1–2B β€” far less than the $5B invested externally and who knows how much originally put in by its founder, Nathan Myhrvold. It's likely that it's heavily subsidized by the patent buying and licensing business (i.e., the troll part). The intriguing open question is whether IV could pay for itself with spin-offs alone?

Traditional philanthropic funding (donations)

Donations without any hope of monetary return seems like an obvious way to fund things that need to be public goods in order to have an impact.

The biggest advantage of donation-based income is that an organization can unabashedly work on things that won't generate a profit. The ability to decouple from profit is a fairly self-explanatory boost in freedom of action. A more subtle benefit is that external researchers and organizations might be more willing to collaborate because (non-political) nonprofits are perceived as having fewer ulterior motives.

There are several successful or promising research organizations funded entirely by traditional philanthropy. Among them are the Allen AI Institute , the Howard Hughes Medical Institute (HHMI) , the Santa Fe Institute , the Gates Foundation , the Chan Zuckerberg Initiative , and Wellcome Leap . 174 The latter three blur the line between "research funding" and "research execution," but so does DARPA. While not a research institute per se, the XPRIZE Foundation is a good example of a philanthropically funded innovation organization that pioneered a weird new model. At the same time, the fate of many organizations like Willow Garage illustrates that doing paradigm-shifting, well-regarded, visionary work is not sufficient to bring in enough donations to fuel an organization.

While not being beholden to investors or customers creates a lot of freedom, donation-based income comes with a whole raft of constraints.

People don't like giving away money. Furthermore, the reticence tends to be supralinear with the amount of money (regardless of the total wealth fraction that money represents). Fundraising for anything is hard; even more so when there is no potential return on that money.

While companies (hopefully) get to profitability after a few fundraising rounds, donation-based income never escapes the fundraising game. Investors like VC or hedge funds are in a similar situation, but the differences between them and charities is illustrative. The key difference between donation- and investment-based funds is that the latter has a clear metric (usually internal rate of return) that it can use to encourage future investment, despite the whole "Past performance is not indicative of future results" rigamarole. A donation-funded organization that tries to have an equally clear metric will inevitably fall victim to Goodhart's Law. 175 Raising money without a metric means that you're completely at the whims of people's feelings. Bluntly, most people give money to philanthropy to make themselves look and feel good.

Raising money without a metric forces an organization to do a lot of "donor management." In addition to time and money (charity balls, anyone?), you need to show progress every time you ask for money β€” once or twice a year. 176 Because most donors can't or don't want to get into the weeds, these progress reports need to take the form of shiny demos which can end up distracting from the core mission or worse, biasing the entire organization toward programs that create shiny demos.

Donation-based income is especially vulnerable to economic downturns. Economy-coupled funding is especially dangerous for long-term research because most researchers are not fungible. You can't just lay off researchers and hire them back when there's more money. Labs will find different sources of funding, and talented people will always be in demand somewhere. Even if you could, programs would take a massive hit β€” the nature of research makes it impossible to start back up exactly where you left off.

It's also important to consider the scale of donors and donations and the associated trade-offs. On one end of the spectrum are individuals giving a few dollars, and on the other end you have an organization like Wellcome Leap or the Allen AI Institute, funded by a single massive foundation.

A brief aside on terminology: So far, we've managed to avoid the terms "nonprofit" and "charity" when talking about donation-funded organizations. These terms are tricky because they have both colloquial meanings but are also legal designations that come with a slew of implications β€” especially around taxes and allowed activities. These implications warp behavior enough that it would be sloppy to flip between using (little-n) nonprofit β€” an organization that is not seeking to maximize profits β€” and (big-N) Nonprofit β€” an organization incorporated under section 501(c)(3) of the US tax code. To avoid confusion for everyone, I'm going to try to use "Charity," "Nonprofit," and "Foundation" in the legal sense and capitalize them to remind you of that usage.

The many-small-donors end of the spectrum tends to push organizations toward either short-termism or constrained sizes. You'll notice that Charities that depend on many small donations are constantly asking for donations β€” everybody has seen Wikipedia's yearly banner; many of us remember asking for pennies for UNICEF on Halloween. Even if they aren't cash-strapped, Charities need to get 33% of their income from "small donors" 177 in order to maintain their legal status (and associated tax benefits for themselves and donors). HowStuffWorks has a reasonable explainer . "Yeah, we're still struggling with the same experiments we were last year" is a common occurrence in research, but isn't a great way to get people excited about donating, nudging charities toward shorter time horizons and flashier results.

Small donors also make funding even more unpredictable than the economy-coupling you would expect from any donation-based funding. If you have a few large donors, you can stay in touch and at least get a heads up on whether they're thinking about donating this year.

There are a few "independent researchers" whose incomes depend on donations through platforms like Patreon and GitHub Sponsors . These folks forgo the tax benefits and funding requirements of being a legal Charity in favor of longer-term funding stability. Empirically, this approach seems to be able support an individual, but not a team or work that has large capital requirements. However, this corner of the funding maze seems underexplored and might be able to be productively combined with membership models , or something similar.

The few-massive-donors end of the philanthropic spectrum is dominated by large Foundations. Outside of a few Foundations that are directly controlled by their founders, most are controlled by professional managers. Professionally managed Foundations usually fall into the asymmetric career risk trap β€” managers are punished for funding something risky that fails but get relatively little upside from funding something risky that succeeds. As a result, Foundations want to see clear metrics, updates, and de-risking on the money they give out. In reality, it's shockingly hard to get professionally managed foundations to do weird new things.

Given the issues with small donors and professionally managed Foundations, a common refrain is: "Just find a few wise, long-term-thinking billionaires and you're set!" This is lazy thinking for several reasons.

  1. There are only 2,095 billionaires in the world as of 2020. Being a billionaire doesn't shift your chances of being wise and good at long-term thinking too much 😱 so there just aren't that many wise, long-term-thinking billionaires.
  2. Wise, long-term-thinking billionaires already have a bajillion people banging down their doors for money because everybody else has the same thought.
  3. Partially as a result, many wise, long-term thinking-billionaires have already bucketed their philanthropic dollars into a foundation.
  4. Being worth a billion dollars on paper doesn't mean that someone has a billion dollars in a bank account they can actually give away.
  5. Perception of money isn't strictly a fraction of how much money you have β€” tens of millions of dollars is a lot of money, period.
  6. If a single person is bankrolling an entire project, they (for good reason!) tend to feel some ownership over it. Depending on the person, this attitude may be problematic for an organization that benefits from opacity and independence. See the section " Opacity is important to DARPA's outlier success " from "Why Does DARPA Work?"
  7. A single source of funding means a single point of failure for the organization if the funder decides to pull out β€” a not-uncommon occurrence. The upshot is not that it's a bad idea to consider funding from wealthy individuals but that it is a bad idea for that to be the only plan.

(Legally designated) Nonprofits are subject to a raft of requirements and constraints about what they can and cannot do without losing their Nonprofit status (and thus loading donors with a host of unexpected taxes). The yearly small-donor requirement on Charities is just one of them. The existence of multiple, ill-defined actions that a Nonprofit is not allowed to take is especially problematic for an organization where it's unclear a priori what it's going to take to achieve an R&D goal and wants to be able to move quickly.

People who donate money generally expect that money will not be used to enrich any individual. However, it's nebulous a priori which research should produce public goods vs. private goods. Sometimes the best way for a technology to have an impact is as part of a private, for-profit enterprise. This tension would need to be treated carefully.

Philanthropic investing

Philanthropic investing sits in a gray zone between a donation and an investment and is definitely worth investigating for a DARPA-riff. "Philanthropic investing" can happen in one of two ways: when a Foundation makes a return-producing investment out of the money that it's spending on its "charitable mission" 180 or when they make a risky investment out of their endowment. 181 In both cases, the foundation is bending the normal rules in order to make an investment that's aligned with the Foundation's mission. Under normal circumstances, Foundations can only use their "programmatic" money to give grants to 501(c)(3) organizations ('Big-N" Nonprofits 182 ) and endowments can only make "non-risky" 183 investments.

The potential to tap into donor-advised funds is another reason for a DARPA-riff to think about philanthropic investing. Donor-advised funds (DAFs) are like Foundations" weird younger siblings: Both organizations are vehicles for wealthy folks to philanthropically spend their money; Foundations give their founders more control but have more overhead and restrictions; DAFs require less initial capital, so they appeal to many wealthy-but-not-name-you-know-wealthy folks. For our purposes, one of the biggest differences is that unlike Foundations, DAFs don't have a payout requirement. As a result, there is a lot of earmarked-for-charity-eventually money sitting around collecting dividends. See " Zombie philanthropy: The rich have stashed billions in donor-advised charities β€” but it's not reaching those in need" (paywalled). The hypothesis is that (in part because they have smaller staffs to evaluate non-money metrics) philanthropic investments are a way to connect DAF money to research projects. See " Donor-Advised Funds: an underutilized philanthropic vehicle to support innovation in science and engineering " for many more details.

A DARPA-riff's ability to take advantage of philanthropic investing is a complex dance with its own structure. Return-producing investments made from a Foundation's charitable spending (also called program-related investments, or PRIs) can happen through several mechanisms. These mechanisms include "recoverable grants" directly to a for-profit organization or funding through an intermediary Nonprofit. For a more in-depth flowchart of the different ways PRIs can happen based on different constraints, see " Foundations: exploring the emerging practice of philanthropic investing to support innovation in science and engineering ." If a DARPA-riff were organized as a for-profit organization, it could get income directly from a recoverable grant; if it were organized as a Nonprofit, it could only act as an intermediary for research that had already budded off into its own organization. Depending on the exact legal requirements for these different funding vehicles, direct grants or loans may require programs to be separate entities from the umbrella organizations and thus may be appropriate for more advanced (post-seedling) programs.

It's likely that philanthropic investing will primarily need to be done on a program-by-program basis. The funding needs to align with each funder's specific mission, so there will also most likely be a lot of fiddling involved to match programs with funders that will require constant inputs of time and effort. Many programs might not align with any causes, because charitable causes tend to be focused on "problems" and DARPA-like programs tend to focus on "more amazing" rather than "less bad." Program-by-program funding would require the umbrella organization to find a different source of funding for things that aren't full-fledged programs, like seedling efforts that could possibly go nowhere. Earmarked philanthropic investments would also limit the fungibility of funds between different programs that allow DARPA to take on more risk. See the section "It is relatively easy for DARPA PMs to re-deploy funding " from "Why Does DARPA Work?"

This is all rather speculative. In contrast to the fairly-well-trodden paths of technology licensing, spin-offs, and donations, philanthropic investing is a relatively new thing. The core hypothesis is that DAFs and Foundations would be more likely to give if there were some chance that they could recover some of the investment (so that they could fund more good things). Prime Coalition is one of the pioneers in the area. They use recoverable grants to do equity funding of for-profit companies. If you squint at it, a DARPA-riff could have the same relationship to Prime Coalition's structure as a startup studio does to a VC firm.

Membership model

A DARPA-riff could generate some free cash flow from a membership model where other organizations pay to be part of a "business network" where they get access to special events, a first crack at research, and help implementing it. The MIT Media Lab's funding consortium is the most prominent (and successful) example of this approach.

Relative operational freedom (if managed correctly) is potentially the biggest upside of the membership model. It can provide short-term liquidity without needing to provide either a monetary ROI like an investment while having perhaps less volatility than charity if you can convince organizations to buy longer-term memberships.

In addition to money, the membership model could help more technology get out into the world. One of the most failure-prone points in technological development is when a technology needs to move from an organization that focuses on R&D to one that focuses on marketing and manufacturing. Having large organizations with marketing and manufacturing capabilities in the loop and already "bought in" 188 could reduce a lot of friction. A membership model could help shepherd frontier technologies with bespoke sales channels in the same way that some pharma investors" main role is as a smooth pipeline through the FDA approval process to acquisition. Short of a program literally becoming the marketing and manufacturing organization for the technology it worked on, 189 a DARPA-riff needs to interface with external orgs to smooth transitions to maximize its impact, with or without a membership model.

A less-tried version of the membership model would extend it beyond big companies to individuals as well. This extended membership model would almost be a hybrid between charity and providing a "product" in the sense of enabling people to be a part of something bigger. How many people would sign up to be SpaceX members? Probably a lot! The closest analogue is probably independent researchers who fund their work through Patreon. See " Reflections on 2020 As an Independent Researcher " for a more in-depth description of this approach. There are many unexplored and potentially exciting paths surrounding individual memberships β€” point systems; tying donations to individual units of work or purchases; community participation in the research itself. The biggest open question is whether an agglomeration of small individual memberships can fund more than a small team. For all the people who would be excited to be SpaceX members, would they even fund a single starship test launch?

Unfortunately, the membership model will probably be unable to fund operations on its own. The MIT Media Lab is probably the most successful organization using this model, and its operating budget is only $45M See http://catalog.mit.edu/mit/research/mit-media-lab/ . (approximately four average-sized DARPA programs). It's unlikely that a DARPA-riff could do much better. Additionally, expenses with fuzzy ROIs are often the first to get cut from organizational budgets during lean times, so membership-based income won't be particularly stable. Notoriously, the Media Lab's incentives drive it to constantly put out shiny demos that ultimately go nowhere. Member management β€” putting on events, making half-finished projects sounds exciting β€” could take up time and resources.

These constraints mean that a membership model is certainly a promising income stream but should probably be coupled with other income sources.

Government grants and contracts

While 21st-century riffs on DARPA should be private , the government gives both grants and contracts to plenty of private organizations. Would a DARPA-riff be able to take advantage of them?

Government grants

The advantage of government grants is that they come with relatively* 192 few strings attached. Nominally, governments don't care about direct monetary ROI 193 and can act on long time scales. The government can actually capture value from public goods, so their incentives are nominally aligned 194 with an organization whose goal is to create impactful technology. Governments also deploy a massive amount of money so the operating budget of a DARPA-riff isn't outrageous compared to other expenditures.

While multi-year government grants are more stable than donations that you need to worry about on a yearly or semi-yearly cycle, they are often one-off events. As a result, an organization that depends on government grants for income needs to spend a significant chunk of time applying for and administering those grants.

There's also a question of which grants specifically we're talking about. Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) grants are one obvious answer. These grants are explicitly designed to fund private R&D that has the potential for commercialization. However, the money from SBIRs is often barely worth the time spent to get it: "Although the applications [for less than $1M] may only be 10 or so pages long, companies should budget at least 80 full-time hours to complete them." See " How to access "America's Seed Fund," the $3 billion SBIR program ." So SBIRs are ... less than optimal, meaning that it will be a job to even hunt down the right grants to apply for.

Despite coming with relatively few incentive-warping strings, government grants do come with plenty of restrictions on how the money can be spent. Most government grant money is earmarked β€” either to be spent on a specific project or for a specific purpose, like salaries or equipment. 196 Spending restrictions are clearly problematic when you want to be able to do whatever is necessary to get the work done. It's unlikely that a DARPA-riff would be able to get much grant money that wasn't tied to a specific program. You would also need to either contort what the organization is working on to align with existing government funding priorities or do a lot of work to convince people to shift those priorities.

Government grants also tend to either fall into the under $1M or over $100M range, both of which are suboptimal for a DARPA-riff. Going for non-standard grant sizes will require a lot of work. You also need to convince people in the government that this weird institutional structure is important and worth funding. In other words, a lot of lobbying (or, put more bluntly, rent-seeking) would be involved.

Government contracts

Government contracts are like grants with more clearly defined deliverables. Unlike selling products, the payment is upfront and the "deliverable" doesn't necessarily need to be as polished and stand alone as a product. The deliverable could be the output of a piece of research or a proof of concept.

SRI International is a great case study of an innovation organization whose income is primarily based on contracts. Arguably, SRI is co-responsible for many of DARPA's triumphs β€” Douglas Engelbart did the work that resulted in the Mother of All Demos at SRI β€” and has spun off many valuable and well-regarded organizations. Including Intuitive Surgical, E-Trade, Symantec β€” see this Wikipedia page for a full list. At the same time, they're also the prime example for the constraints below.

Contracts have advantages over both grants and equity funding. Research contracts can be much larger than grants while still enabling work that might not result in a product. There are fewer restrictions on how you can deploy money from contracts, and at least part of that money comes in before doing the work, so you can hire necessary people and buy equipment.

Depending on contracts as a primary source of income pushes an organization to increasingly resemble a government contractor despite lofty goals otherwise. Once you start playing the government contracting game, the path of least resistance is to become a government contractor. Even with this possibility in mind, it's impossible work on government contracts without slight organizational warping. You need to spend time and effort paying attention to which contracts are available, bidding for them, and administering them, so contracts aren't something that you can easily do occasionally and opportunistically.

Contracts are fairly unpredictable. SRI International, for example, has regular boom and bust cycles, where they hire many people to work on a particular project and then need to fire them when they no longer have contracts to work on. Unpredictability might be slightly less of a problem if more of the work is externalized, but it would still be problematic for long-term projects.

Obviously, the biggest problem with contracts is that you don't have much control over what you're working on. In a best-case scenario, you can find an existing call for something that you already need to do or a slight extension of that work. In a less-good scenario, you either end up lobbying to get contracts for what you were going to do anyway or need to heavily shift what you're doing in order to win them. Again, the issue is that in order to maintain the organizational infrastructure to do the former, you'll probably need to at least some of the latter.

Despite all the pitfalls, organizations like Otherlab and many other small engineering firms have managed to get by on grants combined with contracts. However, their work often feels scattered and incomplete. The need to pursue different contracts and grants makes it hard to do the sort of deep long-term work that can lead to extensible breakthroughs.

Consulting

A DARPA-riff could sell program designs to large organizations and provide consulting services for implementing them. There are a number of organizations with similar models; Lux Research charges tens of thousands of dollars for high quality reports on technical areas and the ability to ask questions about them. If the hypothesis is that program design will be a core part of a DARPA-riff, it will already be creating artifacts that larger organizations might be interested in.

A consulting-based income stream has a number of upsides, especially early in a DARPA-riff's life. It could generate early cash before even implementing programs while maintaining relative operational freedom from investors or donors. If the program designs would be important and good for the world (as I would hope all of them are!) it's a win-win, whether or not the large organizations actually execute on the program. If they do execute on it well, it's a cheap demonstration that the program design process works. If they don't execute on it or execute on it poorly, you could still run the program later (assuming there is no reputational blowback to the organization or the program idea itself). Selling knowledge to large companies with manufacturing capabilities could potentially address frontier technology's bespoke sales channel problem. One could imagine a "pipeline" where, even if big organizations don't fully embrace program designs, they nevertheless start to acclimate to the ideas. In this way, there's a fuzzy boundary between consulting and the membership model.

Consulting-based income comes with a slew of downsides. The biggest downside is that consulting wouldn't provide enough cash to support a full-blown steady-state DARPA-riff. That being said, it could be a good way of bringing in income while demonstrating that program design can work. Consulting is a canonical trap for small organizations β€” clients can often pull you in unproductive directions, and you need to spend a significant chunk of time on sales. Another danger is that this income stream would render a DARPA-riff particularly susceptible to working on "hot" areas that are adjacent to high-margin industries. This danger is particularly insidious because the most important things to work on may be unsexy areas adjacent to low-margin industries.

The mitochondria maneuver: Be an independent-ish arm of some existing money factory

As we've beaten to death by now, a DARPA-riff would fill a niche in the innovation ecosystem that was once filled by industrial labs. While new industrial labs created inside of corporations are probably not viable, it might be possible for an external organization to become a corporation's industrial lab while maintaining process and culture that supports high quality solutions R&D. This strategy toward long-term survival is "the mitochondria maneuver": Get absorbed into a larger organization while maintaining a permeable barrier and your own cultural and operational DNA.

The benefits are pretty clear, if they don't require neutering your organization to get them. Innovation organizations need a money factory, and what better money factory than a big company that is already making massive profits? The budget from the larger org is effectively dividends from an endowment.

Arguably, DeepMind is a great example of the mitochondria maneuver. 198 An AI research lab, they were acquired by Google in 2014, but unlike most acquired companies, they have maintained relative independence to do high-quality long-term work. 199 As long as they continue to have hits every few years (AlphaGo, AlphaFold) and some of their work directly helps the mothership (some of their work makes Google's data centers more efficient), Alphabet seems willing to heavily subsidize their almost $1B budget. See " DeepMind revenue dwarfed by $649 million loss." However, the fact that the Alphabetβ€”DeepMind relationship meets the three criteria for healthy industrial labs should make you skeptical whether the mitochondria maneuver can be accomplished in other (lower-margin, less clearly aligned) domains.

While they're under the same constraints in the long run, a key difference between a mitochondrial organization and a home-grown lab may be the ability to skate where the puck is going. A "normal" industrial lab needs to justify its existence from day one β€” "stakeholder buy-in" and all that. By contrast, a mitochondrial organization only needs that justification eventually. DeepMind officially started in 2010 β€” two years before AlexNet acted like lightning to AI hype's thunder. It's hard to put yourself in the mind-set of pre-2012 attitudes toward AI research, but the term "AI winter" exists for a reason. Suffice to say, it seems unlikely that any corporation would have created a full-fledged AI-focused lab in 2010. 201 This framework suggests that a key requirement for the mitochondria maneuver to work is a strong thesis about how your DARPA-riff's focus will align with a high-margin corporation's priorities in the future.

A DARPA-riff cannot count on the mitochondria maneuver from day one. During its Odyssean wanderings, it will still need to depend on one of the other income sources. However, some income streams might be more conducive to eventually getting absorbed than others β€” a membership model or programmatic consulting could both become more and more serious until two organizations decide to go steady and consummate their relationship.

Attempting the mitochondria maneuver seems fraught with failure modes. It basically requires predicting the future, which is hard. (Though easier if you're doing that by inventing it.) 202 The steps an organization might need to take to survive might make it unpalatable for a corporation. The opposite could also happen! And while DeepMind has done well, history is littered with organizations that thought they were going to become their acquirer's R&D arm but the fates had other things in store for them.

An endowment that funds operations out of the interest on a large principal seems like the ideal funding mechanism for a DARPA-riff

Ultimately, a DARPA-riff needs to be autocatalytic. The only way for it to be able to plan and act over long time scales is to fund operations through predictable, long-term income that doesn't distract from the core goal. Unfortunately, these criteria rule out many funding sources for "steady state" operations. One of the only ways to satisfy them all may be to build an endowment.

Most of the income streams we've explored aren't suitable to fund a DARPA-riff over the long run. For income to be predictable, it can't disappear at the whims of either a few individuals or large mobs β€” so grants, philanthropy, and contracts aren't viable as steady-state funding sources. Technology licensing and membership models can't generate enough revenue to fully fund steady-state operations. Creating and selling products or services can create predictable long-term income. However, it seems hard to avoid sales-based income distracting from the core goal when that goal is in part to enable things that are not product-focused enough for startups. Similarly, it would be very hard to avoid an investment-in-spin-offs-based income stream creating incentives to spin off more things with ever bigger, nearer-term exits. Spin-off-based income might work in steady state, but to count on it alone would be to enter the same incentive regime as VCs. The mitochondria maneuver is one explicitly steady-state option, but it requires a fairly narrow set of conditions.

The magically ideal steady-state income source for a DARPA-riff is an endowment that can fund operations from its interest. An endowment could create a near-infinite time horizon with minimal pandering to external stakeholders. Of course, getting to that point will take a long time and may be impossible!

Perpetual endowments have precedent for enabling different research paradigms β€” the Rockefeller Foundation , Howard Hughes Medical Institute , and Wellcome Trust have all done great work.

What would the ideal steady-state budget of a DARPA-riff be? As some anchor points, DARPA's 2020 budget was $3.6B See " Department of Defense Fiscal Year (FY) 2020 Budget Estimates ." and Bell Labs" 1974 budget was weirdly similar at $2.8B in 2021 dollars. See " The End of AT&T " (this might require a free account login). If it's true that research orgs don't scale, these historical anecdotes suggest that a single-digit billion-dollar budget may be the upper limit for an effective research organization. This argument is admittedly hand-wavy, but it provides a useful anchor for the high end of a long-term DARPA-riff budget. Being aggressively ambitious, let's say ~$1B/year. This number is less than DARPA and the fully evolved form of Bell Labs but more than Bell Labs" 1930 budget of $300M in 2021 dollars. See The Making of American Industrial Research: Science and Business at GE and Bell 1876–1926 .

A back-of-the-envelope calculation tells us that to hit a $1B budget, assuming 4% dividends on invested capital, you would need a $25B endowment. That is an absurd but not unthinkably large number. For comparison, Harvard, Yale, and Stanford have endowments of $41B, $31B, and $29B, respectively, as of 2019. See the list on Wikipedia here . Howard Hughes Medical Institute had $21.2B in assets in 2020. See HHMI financials . Admittedly, these are the largest endowments in the world so the chances of being able to get there are incredibly low. However, they stand as proof points that a long-term goal to build an endowment that could support a $1B budget is hard but not impossible. 208

Even endowment-based funding is not without pitfalls. Endowment-based funding's boon and bane is that it dampens feedback loops. As a result, the organization could become decoupled from its original goal as new generations of people (specially professional managers) take over. While this problem is not inevitable, the distinct possibility emphasizes the importance of long-term focused governance structures and intergenerational culture.

Another potential downside of loose feedback loops is that mission-focused organizations run the risk of perverse incentives when they come close to achieving their mission. Instead of closing up shop at a job well done, mission-focused organizations can wind up exaggerating the prevalence of a problem or slacking on the job in order to remain relevant. Luckily for a DARPA-riff, I'm not too worried about running out of possibly potentially game-changing but otherwise unsupportable projects.

Another minor consideration is that the other side of endowment-based funding's stability is that it can't quickly scale up. That doesn't seem like a significant limitation because we can expect DARPA-riffs to be more ideas-limited than money-limited. See " What makes DARPA tick ?" Anecdotally, a DARPA director once asked for Congress to decrease their budget, lest they be crushed under the accompanying expectations.

Of course, the biggest question is: How do you build an endowment in the first place?

Let's rule out the possibility of acquiring the money all at once for three reasons. First is the obvious one: Anybody with a chunk of money that big burning a hole in their pocket already has plans for it. Second, it is important for big things to start small β€” the organization needs the flexibility to work out kinks and develop a culture without the pressure to deploy a massive amount of money. Third, most people with the ability to create an endowment of that size would (reasonably!) want near direct control of the organization, which would likely as not lead to headaches. See this essay by Paul Graham about unrestricted donations

Ruling out one big funding event means that a DARPA-riff will need to build an endowment up over time, depending on the other funding sources we've explored in this section. Through a conscious process of budgetary discipline, the organization could squirrel away funds, perhaps helped by a windfall here and there. Again, an endowment is a possibly unreachable goal, but it's one of those low-probability events whose probability drops to zero if you don't shoot for it.

Speculation

Exploratory program organizations

One potential experiment is that each program could be its own semi-independent entity β€” an exploratory program organization (EPO). You could imagine it as a legal entity that enables a research program to smoothly slide between the fully externalized research that DARPA coordinates and the internalized research of an organization like Lockheed Skunk Works.

DARPA doesn't do any research in house. Externalized research has benefits, especially at the beginning of high-risk programs. It can act as a buffer against B-players, allows you to tap into tacit knowledge and specialized equipment without going all in, and more. Externalized research also has downsides that increase as the research matures. Dependencies between different parts of any research program tend to increase as the program matures, increasing the coordination costs if everybody involved isn't under the same roof. Anybody who has done a group project has experienced this: It starts with, "You go figure out how we'll do path planning and I'll figure out how to talk to the motor," but the division of labor breaks down when you actually need the motor to do the path planning! These trade-offs mean that there's no constant correct level of internal/external research throughout a program. It's even possible that one reason DARPA has a mixed record on transitioning is because their pure externalized research makes it hard to cohere the different projects within a program into a single system.

At the beginning of a program, externalized research is important for building conviction. Externalized research enables the program to have access to rare skills or equipment that might only exist in one or two places in the world. Perhaps there is just one researcher who has perfected the technique for synthesizing a particular molecule. Externalized research allows the program to tap into people who would only want to work part-time or have other commitments, like finishing a PhD. One of the big barriers to starting a company is that founders need to be 100% in or there is weird, murky uncertainty. Many DARPA programs would have been killed by these coordination costs if they had to be self-contained organizations from day one.

At the end of a program, internalized work is important for bringing disparate pieces of a program together and commercializing or otherwise "encapsulating" a technology so other people can use it. While it's possible, there are very few examples of successful decentralized productization, and someone needs to buy technology eventually .

In its early stages, an EPO could look similar to a DARPA program, with a program manager coordinating externalized research. As the program matures, performers can move from academic labs or other organizations to work directly for the EPO. This internalization lowers coordination costs around system integration once the individual pieces are de-risked. There's something clutch about the ability to go to someone's desk and say, "Hey, look at this" when you're dealing with physical systems. In effect, the program manager is an initial CEO for the EPO, gradually internalizing outputs and people from the externally funded activity.

It is hard to know going into a program what kind of value it will create. Some research programs end up creating something that resembles a product, some end up creating valuable IP, and some just end up creating valuable knowledge without a clear way to capture it. Of course, many programs produce nothing of value at all except good stories. The EPO's structure acknowledges this reality by being temporary and converting to one of several options at the end of its life.

At the end of its life, the EPO could:

  1. Renew for another life if several more years of external research could get the program to a much better place.
  2. Convert into a profit-focused C-corp or LLC if it has reached a point where a product is on the horizon.
  3. Convert into a nonprofit focused on advancing the EPO's research mission if the EPO's focus needs long-term research and coordination but won't be producing a product.
  4. Convert into an organization for licensing IP if the EPO produced valuable IP that doesn't cohere into a product.
  5. Or (in reality, the most likely case) the EPO can do nothing in particular after it expires.

Many EPOs will not work out. That is OK because of the continuously varied commitment and temporary nature. You're not asking investors to put in a ton of money or people to quit their jobs from day one. The high failure rate might suggest that an EPO should be structured to be renewed every year with a maximum lifetime of five years. You wouldn't want a zombie EPO sucking resources for years after it's clear that it won't work.

EPOs could give PMs incentives that DARPA programs cannot β€” the ability to become the leader of an organization devoted to making a vision into a reality. In a way, the PM to EPO leader would systematize Robert Taylor's role in the personal computer: After running the Information Processing Technology Office at ARPA, Taylor spun up the interactive computing group at PARC and recruited the people who had been working on the ARPA program to work there.

EPOs could bridge the Valley of Death. A big "failure" mode of both DARPA and ARPA-E is that nobody takes the technology football when a program successfully wraps up. It's especially insidious because that handoff falls into the cracks between job descriptions so often, someone has to go above and beyond to make it happen. In the book Loonshots , Safi Bahcall uses the pithy aphorism "Manage the transfer, not the technology" to emphasize the point that this handoff, not the technological development itself, is where many promising technologies go to die. Although ARPA-E has a commercialization team, they only try to get the individual pieces of a program commercialized, but do not coordinate them into a single entity. The nature of an EPO removes that gap entirely; the program becomes a new organization that takes the football. A continuous slider from modularized external research to coordinated internalized research also enables people from disciplines farther down the "pipeline" to be involved in the process. For example, prototypes are much more likely to be manufactured if people from manufacturing are in the room during the prototype design.

EPOs probably need a novel legal structure.

A parent organization for the EPOs

You could imagine EPOs acting as stand-alone organizations; something akin to focused research organizations See " Focused Research Organizations to Accelerate Science, Technology, and Medicine ." that initially have a distributed structure. However, EPOs will be drastically more effective with an umbrella organization that can spin them up and maintain the nebulous things that benefit from institutional consistency, like intra-organizational relationships and tacit knowledge. In other words, EPOs are a complement to a DARPA-riff, not a replacement for it.

A DARPA-riff is important for getting EPOs off the ground. Starting EPOs probably involves an involved program design process and scattered experiments to show that it's worthwhile to start. You need another organization to do that work. Additionally, DARPA PMs often work on multiple programs at once, which would be harder to do without a DARPA-riff acting as an umbrella organization. Culture, process knowledge, extra-organizational relationships, and organizational trust that a parent organization could build are intangible but could ultimately make each individual EPO more likely to succeed both in terms of know-how and money.

Since any given EPO is likely to fail, an umbrella organization is important for creating a portfolio of programs and shifting money between them. The portfolio approach enables funders to put money into the parent organization with a much higher chance that it will have a payoff than with any individual EPO. If each EPO needed to raise its own money, it would take a lot of time and resources and they would be incentivized to work on whatever is most likely to be funded, which heavily incentivizes likely-to-work or heavily hyped areas.

Issues

The private companies and labs who DARPA (and hence a DARPA-riff) works with might have a problem with folks leaving to join an EPO. "This might lead to people leaving" might make other organizations hesitant to work with you in the first place. Graduate students and postdocs who are transient members of labs are the obvious exception.

Intellectual property ownership will also be an issue. Companies and universities are willing to work with DARPA at least in part because they know that they will get to keep the IP that comes out of the collaboration. At the same time, large companies work with universities and smaller companies all the time and presumably have satisfactory IP arrangements, so this doesn't seem like an unsolvable problem.

You can create a program design discipline that enables better research and development

There is a lot of literature about how to manage research programs, but very little thinking about how to design them in the first place.

Program design is inextricably tied up with research planning. The idea of planning research might make some people throw up up in their mouths a little bit, See " Fund people, not projects I: The HHMI and the NIH Director's Pioneer Award " and the other parts of the same series for a deep dive on the literature around this. but bear with me. I'm going to put on my Wittgenstein hat See "Wittgenstein: Reality is shaped by the words we use " from Farnam Stree t. and suggest that words matter; what people are actually objecting to is scheduling research around deliverables , which is very different from planning research around goals .

All research is planned around goals to some extent. Even "I'm going to put this liquid in this other liquid and see what happens" is a plan. In this situation, the goal is to see and report on what happens when you mix those two liquids. It's a silly example, but it provides a base case to build off of. The chemist mixing the chemicals probably has a bigger plan than simply seeing what happens; the plan probably involves mixing many combinations of chemicals in order to chase a bigger goal like understanding which combination produces the most heat or perhaps why exothermic reactions exist at all.

Our chemist friend doesn't necessarily have or need a specific deliverable to do good work. It might literally be impossible for her to, for example, find a mixture that produces as much heat as she wants. Even if she could, it might involve testing an order of magnitude more mixtures or even needing to invent an entirely new synthesis technique to do it. Requiring her to work on a specific schedule would be inane. I suspect that deliverables and schedules are artifacts of the commoditization process that happened to research during the 20th century as a by-product of the expansion and institutionalization of science. See " The decline of unfettered research " for a good description of this process and its consequences.

If planning and goal setting (separate from schedules and deliverables) are necessary for any kind of R&D work, it raises several questions. What kind of goals should be set and what time scales should be planned for what sort of work? Should you parallelize work or serialize it? In what contexts? What are the key constraints keeping you from a breakthrough? What level of fidelity will stifle creativity, and what will provide the focus to make breakthroughs? Which tools will maximize the focus and minimize stifling, and which frameworks can make the difference between good work and bad? I would posit that these questions and their ilk, what I might refer to as "program design', are woefully under-theorized.

In addition to the big-headed questions, the objective truth seems to be that we kind of suck at designing researchy programs. Most programs feel like a grab bag of vaguely related projects that are incremental extensions of whatever researchers were already working on but nudged slightly toward a central theme. Most technology roadmaps feel like the penultimate committee output; bland documents that simultaneously seem to say everything but are useless for making hard decisions. There are some exceptions! The International Technology Roadmap for Semiconductors is quite good, I presume because an entire massive industry actually depends on coordinated research. Whether or not we've actually become worse at program design is an open question. To stake a firm position, I will say yes, we have become worse β€” anecdotally, compare F-35 or SLS development to Apollo. This disciplinary decay would be due to reasonable incentives β€” there are fewer areas that need program design to function. Arguably, software has become the dominant "innovation-based industry" and, unlike science-based manufacturing, it doesn't benefit significantly from (and can even be harmed by) long-time-horizon program design.

The question of whether we've become worse at program design is an important preliminary for the more important question: Could we do program design better? 216 If we've gotten worse, it's strong evidence that we could do better. However, I suspect that we can do better regardless of whether we've always sucked at it (or are secretly good at it? πŸ€”) .

One reason program design is under-theorized is that the people who are good at it are too busy applying it to spend time and effort making it legible. 217 There are no research coaches. Program design also suffers acutely from siloization β€” each organization (or individual!) seems to reinvent the wheel. This isn't to say that we should aim for standardization; program design will always be very context-dependent. However, it seems possible to shoot for a baseline of best practices and frameworks for building on top of those best practices.

There are many inspirations that the discipline might be able to draw on. A big part of a program design discipline will be trying to make legible the process that skilled practitioners already use to create things like Adam Marblestone's " Climate Technology Primer " or JosΓ© Luis RicΓ³n's " Longevity FAQ ." RicΓ³n does a good job unpacking his process in " The Longevity FAQ: Making Of "; one could imagine a line of research that focuses on understanding why some people are good at this process and some are not. Adam Marblestone and Ed Boyden hinted at the possibility of more structured discovery in their article " Architecting Discovery ."

History is another place to dig β€” how did people manage research-adjacent projects that had shockingly fast results ? While some of the results were contingent on the individuals involved, I can't shake the hunch that there is transferable knowledge in the tools developed to manage early space programs. See The Secrets of Apollo or the PERT guide for management . How did the creators of the " Fusion Power by Magnetic Confinement " report think about the different possibilities and trade-offs? 219 Of course, the value of historical study depends on the aforementioned question of whether we've become worse or not.

You don't often see this kind of program design anymore. Was it never useful, now outdated, or a lost art?

There has been a lot of relevant work on how to do better project management (as opposed to program management). One could even argue that researchy program design is just part of project management. I would argue that standard project management techniques (Six Sigma Six Sigma is Motorola's process-improvement process. , Matrix Management Matrix management is a now-disfavored project management approach created by the aerospace industry in the 1950s. , etc.) need so much modification to deal with the uncertainty, time scales, and fractured expertise inherent in research programs that we're talking about something beyond a simple extension of project management. There is a whole range of methodologies like TRIZ See And Suddenly the Inventor Appeared: Triz, the Theory of Inventive Problem Solving . , Wigmore charts , and Wardley maps , that feel like they have nuggets of truth but are, for the most part, post-hoc explanations of success used to get consulting gigs in areas with loose feedback loops like big companies and law schools. So, like any good discipline, program design would start strongly adjacent to crackpots and mysticism! 223

What might a Wardley-inspired roadmap for describing the complete structural connectivity of the human brain look like?

There are several areas that I suspect are important for good program design where I haven't found much written prior art (unless you squint very hard): systematic ways to think about technological constraints and tradeoffs; ways to visually represent constraints and possibilities in a manner that can actually aid decision-making and reveal new possibilities; and the tactical psychology of creating programs. Each of these areas is something that people already do, but in an ad-hoc way. Anytime someone says something along the lines of, "Oh, you can't do long-range battery-powered commercial flight β€” batteries are too heavy," they're implicitly bundling many constraints and assumptions: What kinds of batteries are we talking about? What is their power density? What components contribute what fraction to their weight? How much power do they need to put out for how long to be useful? What are we assuming about the propulsion systems for the plane? What are the degrees of freedom for all of these components? What are the dependencies between them? How hard would it be to improve any one of those components, by how much, and what would that effect be on the whole system? The same sorts of questions are important for any technology. That many complex questions are also impossible to hold in your head all at once, let alone transfer into someone else's head β€” thus the need for thinking frameworks and representation tools.

And then there's the shockingly human and under-discussed process of mining that knowledge in the first place. Perhaps controversially, I'm convinced that most human knowledge is not encoded, especially on the knowledge frontier. As a consequence, a lot of program design is actually applied psychology. As the program designer, you need to not only nudge people to talk about their areas of expertise in ways that they probably haven't before and generate excitement about the idea of a bigger program, you also need to figure out who are the right people to talk to and get them to talk to you in the first place! This piece of program design resembles some combination of sales and user research. Equally (or perhaps more!) important to the question of "What work needs to be done?" is "Who is best suited to do the work?" It's quite funny, actually β€” while there seems to be a strong cultural consensus that good outcomes in high-uncertainty endeavors depend heavily on the specific individuals involved, answers to the question "Who is best suited to do this work?" are almost entirely absent when people lay out a research program.

It's important to acknowledge that this entire hypothesis that you can create a program design discipline could easily be false. Perhaps guiding research is more like creating art; one can talk about specific techniques ( art : stenciling, mixing paints, shadows; program design : talking to experts, budgeting, evaluating claims), but the process itself is too context-dependent and holistic to improve through the tools and abstractions that a discipline would provide. Perhaps more dangerous is the possibility that any formalization ventures out of the realm of planning and goals and into the realm of schedules and deliverables, hamstringing the work you intend to enable.

Another strong argument against the formalization of program design is that the real issues are Rumsfeldian unknown unknowns that are undiscoverable or unthinkable before you run into them in the process of doing the work. Paradigm shifts are to some extent unimaginable before they happen by definition. The presumption that we could do a better job than practitioner intuition could be a foolish waste of brain cycles at best, or actively steer people away from actually useful work at worst. "How do you draw a roadmap off the edge of the map?" is a valid question.

The possible upsides of a healthy program design discipline seem like they could be huge. So if you go in explicitly acknowledging the potential failure modes, the potential upsides are worth it. Program design could potentially help programs to exist that would not exist otherwise, prevent wild goose chases, and unlock unintuitive possibilities!

The trick is that to do risky experiments 224 , program design as a discipline needs to be embedded in an organization running programs. Enabling technologies must be developed while doing serious work, See How can we develop transformative tools for thought? and without an organizational home, program design would be severed from a serious context of use. It would suffer the same fate as other academic or consultant-driven disciplines of practice. These disciplines tend to sound great on paper so that someone wants to implement them, but that implementation often has so many restrictions, imperfect information, and strung-out feedback loops that it's unclear how much of the success or failure of the project is attributable to the discipline. Developing better program design is one of the reasons why, despite the fact that running multiple organizational experiments flies in the face of common wisdom, a DARPA-riff both can and must do multiple experiments at once .

Program design is like creating a Lego instruction book

'Program design" is an awfully nebulous term. Its centrality to any DARPA-riff makes it worth spending some time wrapping our heads around. Like many nebulous things, the best way to think about program design may be through an extended analogy. If you didn't build Lego sets as a kid, I recommend you pause reading, buy one, build it, and then resume.

Modern research institutions tend to produce a lot of atomic contributions. These contributions resemble Lego bricks in the sense that you can intuit that while they are not useful on their own, they will be useful as part of a broader system. But like most Lego bricks it's not immediately clear what amazing thing the brick can eventually be part of. (And in fact it can be part of many things!) Even a giant bucket of Lego bricks often doesn't immediately suggest what to build. This bucket of bricks is the state of many disciplines. That description is too extreme β€” the situation is more that we have the picture on the front of the box and the bricks that came in the box mixed with a bunch of extraneous ones. Thought leaders and big ideas people talk about the different box-pictures all the time; everybody has a vague idea that their brick is a part of the spaceship. But if you've ever put together a Lego set, it's rarely clear where each part fits in until you see all the intermediate steps in the instruction book.

The goal of program design is to create these intermediate steps. For example, the painfully unsexy step 72 that has a bunch of tan and gray pieces in a rough shape with some flanges on it that doesn't look like anything at all. It is hard to know that step 72 is going to lead to the awesome spaceship on the box; it certainly doesn't look like a spaceship.

It's a spaceship, obviously.

Getting step 34 to happen is hard. You need to imagine the unseen interior of what's on the box, which pieces are available, which pieces you would ideally have, and which substitutions are OK. (It doesn't really matter if you use a neon green brick instead of a gray one as an interior part.) If you really need a piece that doesn't exist, you need to make it yourself or convince someone else to make it. And then you need to get all the pieces together β€” just because you put together an actionable plan does not mean people will take those actions!

Ideally, as many steps as possible are relatively self-contained "modules': the cockpit part of the spaceship, a secondary landing craft, an escape pod. In real life, this corresponds to intermediate goals that are useful on their own or are at least exciting milestones or demos. There are many words that should be written about the tension between the benefits of useful intermediate steps and the danger that undue focus on useful intermediate steps can pose to eventual outcomes. In hindsight, it's easy to both look at technological development and forget how many incremental useful steps there were (synthetic plastic was used as a nifty liquid by printers before it was accidentally cooked), and to forget how much work has gone into technologies before they get to anything useful (transistors needed eight years of work before the first completely unusable point-contact demonstration).

Obviously, this analogy can only be pushed so far: Research-heavy programs will inevitably have gaps between steps that would make any Lego assembler tear her hair out; the picture on the front of the box might be fuzzy or wrong; in real life, pieces don't just snap together; technology doesn't exist independent of people, so you need to deal with incentives, politics, and egos; and more.

You could reasonably object to this analogy with a counter-analogy that the pieces of a research program are less like Legos and more like biological components. Separate components in a biological process have much more "agency" β€” if you create the right environment and shake it or apply a jolt of electricity, they will self-assemble. See the Miller–Urey experiment . The biological analogy would be much more apt than a Lego analogy if paradigm-shifting work cannot be planned or the innovation ecosystem is "directionally" correct and just needs more funding and work along existing channels.

I suspect the reality is a mix of both analogies β€” in research programs, unlike Lego construction, you can't lay out every single step, so "biological" self-assembly between steps will be essential. Keep in mind that these analogies are meant as thinking tools, not evidence or predictive descriptions of the world. Hopefully, though, the Lego analogy is provocative. Playing with it is a more tangible way to describe the need for program design overall and suggests extensions, like the the possible role of simulations and legible intermediate steps.

Good simulations could be the "why now" of roadmapping tools

New technologies and disciplines are often good ideas in theory but infeasible in practice because they're built on top of other technologies that aren't up to snuff. Electric cars that are comparable to gasoline-powered cars weren't really feasible until the electronics industry caused leaps in lithium-ion batteries. "Why now?" is a good question to ask whenever someone proposes a new technology or discipline. A good answer can hint at eventual success. Of course, the many examples of successful creations that didn't have a particular "why now" means that a bad answer to the question doesn't predict failure. Simulations may be an answer to the "why now" question for a new program design discipline: Our capability to simulate everything from proteins to cities has exploded in the 21st century, and simulations have a unique ability to precisely illustrate possibilities that do not yet exist in a way that is both internally consistent and externally consistent.

Simulations have continuously improved over the late 20th century and early 21st century, thanks to improvements in both software and hardware. 227 Games and movies have pushed the edge of the possible, encouraging better algorithms, processes, and tools. Improvement in graphics processing units (GPUs) both directly enables better simulations (the world is massively parallel!) and has fueled improvements in machine learning, which has recently started unlocking simulation capabilities like AlphaFold and FermiNet. See " AlphaFold: Using AI for scientific discovery " and " FermiNet: Quantum Physics and Chemistry from First Principles ."

With simulations, you can precisely work backward from a long-term goal technology. This "backward propagation" can then be used to inform what you build starting with what is possible today. In a way, this role is similar to the one fulfilled by science fiction when you use it as a case study, or simply a precise vision of where a technology can go. However, simulations are much more precise than visions and can be not only a compass but a map as well. They can surface obstacles and make non-intuitive suggestions about which routes might be productive and which might be traps.

Take "atomically precise manufacturing", for example. There is one camp that says "There's no reason it shouldn't work" but doesn't give clear examples of what "working" would actually look like. There is another camp that says "That's not how molecules work!" but, like the proponents, can't be any more grounded. With that level of discourse, the two groups inevitably just talk past each other, which makes it hard for even a technically trained outsider to evaluate their arguments. In a way, it resembles the post-consensus political discourse. If both groups could agree to the assumptions and methods behind a simulation, it would be possible to create more or less objective evidence for or against the feasibility of one plan or another. The simulations could then enable researchers 229 to iterate on precise challenges.

Even more optimistically, simulations could enable non-researchers to contribute as well! If you squint, video games are simply simulations optimized for fun instead of accuracy. One could imagine many [games? tools?] somewhere between Foldit and Kerbal Space Program that enable non-experts to explore possibility space and surface approaches orthogonal to expert thinking.

Of course there are challenges. To name a few: It is hard to interface different simulations; it is hard to know where a simulation diverges from reality; and simulations and models often fail to capture important aspects of a real system. Like any intellectual tool, simulations can be used well and poorly. People often claim that an idea works "in simulation" without laying out the assumptions behind that simulation and without any connection to how it might be physically implemented. So this isn't to say that simulations can address every problem right now. However, the space of problems that simulations can potentially unlock has significantly expanded in the past several years (as of 2021).

A DARPA-riff could use a constitution with checks and balances to produce high variance-results over a long period of time

The DARPA model is an unbuffered system. In chemistry, an unbuffered system changes its overall pH rapidly in response to acids or bases. At DARPA, individual contributions easily have a huge effect on outcomes. An unbuffered system has many advantages β€” most notably, it enables high-agency individuals to act quickly with minimal friction. At the same time, an unbuffered system seems likely to run into a catastrophic failure that kills the whole thing. In order to do effective solutions R&D, a DARPA-riff needs to be a long-term institution. Is it possible to build in checks and balances that could sustain a long-term institution without ruining the possibility of high-variance outputs?

Looking far outside the realm of research organizations, it's worth noting that there are some core elements of the American Constitution that have made the United States a rather robust institution. 230 The US founders thought a lot about institutional longevity, and it's worth drawing from their experience. As a thought experiment, let's go back to sixth grade civics class. (For those readers who didn't go to school in the US, you really didn't miss much.) We can examine the roles of different branches of government and play with them through the lens of the different building blocks we have in corporate governance and DARPA's structure. I'll pay special attention to the Buxton Index (the length of the period over which an entity makes its plans) of each role to explicitly call out where there will be incentive mismatches. Ideally, you can use those tensions as a productive set of checks and balances instead of generating wasteful friction.

Different roles as different branches of government

It seems pretty clear that the program managers (PMs), as the people who are actually executing on the programs, are analogous to the American Executive Branch. Similar to the Executive Branch, they probably have the lowest Buxton Index. Remember, PMs have a tenure of four to five years. PMs are also the outward facing piece of the institution, similar to the role of the Executive Branch.

The role of the Judicial Branch seems well served by some kind of multi-person board of directors (which is an awkward juxtaposition with the "director" titles usually held by DARPA managers so we'll just call it the board for now). Like the Judicial Branch it makes sense for the board to be the farthest removed from the day-to-day operations of the organization. Also similar to the Judicial Branch (and other boards), it seems like a good starting place to have it be composed of several people with indefinite term limits, giving it both the highest Buxton Index and the lowest variance; we can use the fact that decisions made by committees lead to median results in our favor.

That leaves the director(s) as the Legislative Branch . At first, this connection seems a bit odd because we're juxtaposing a bicameral legislature and at most a few people (and likely just one person β€” at least at first). However, taking a step back and looking at the Legislative Branch as the internally facing branch that writes the laws, the connection makes more sense. The director will have a Buxton Index that is somewhere between the PMs and the board and be responsible for setting culture and procedures, money, and other internal functions that are roughly analogous to laws.

The last piece of the puzzle is a constitution and a body of laws. Most corporations have constitutions, but it's usually a formality. Instead, a DARPA-riff should take a constitution seriously as a coordination mechanism. It flies in the face of common wisdom to have written rules early on in an organization's life. However, as a mechanism for enabling institutional longevity, it might be valuable enough to introduce it as a source of friction. Many fast-moving organizations still have very writing-centric cultures. You could take this approach one step further and say that memos constitute a body of laws.

Checks and balances between branches

The checks and balances should be based around two principles: 1. By default, people should be allowed to do things unless they will harm the organization's long-term ability to achieve its goals; and 2. Each branch should be able to check each other branch.

It's standard for a board to appoint CEOs (in this case, directors). This practice fits into our framework. Since there is no electorate, the board is effectively the representative of stakeholders who would otherwise elect the members of the legislature. Similar to the judiciary, the board should be able to step in and stop actions that explicitly go against the organization's written constitution. This less-standard ability gives them a lot of power to check both the Executive and Legislative Branch, but they are only allowed to use it in a very constrained way.

In most corporations, the board has the ability to remove the CEO. Should that be the case in a DARPA-riff? It gives the board a ton of power to warp the director's incentives. My hunch is that it should be possible, but should resemble impeachment in the sense that it needs to be an action of last resort and needs to be non-arbitrary (that is, constitutionally based).

Like the American Legislative Branch's check on the executive, money will be the director's major check on the PMs. For this to work, trust and communication must flow freely in both directions. The director's check on the board is through the written rules, as the board is constrained to only stop actions that go against the written rules. Giving the director an explicit check on the board is one place where we deviate from normal corporate structure.

The PMs/Executive Branch will require some non-standard tools in order to have official checks on the other two branches. Normally, employees don't have an official check outside of perhaps choosing to join or leave an organization. Although their positions are explicitly temporary, you want PMs to be as bought-in to the institution as everybody else. Perhaps even more so. Having their own levers of power are important to that buy-in.

Given that PMs should have checks on the directors and the board, what should they look like? In the US government, the Executive Branch nominates new justices. PMs nominating new board members is unconventional, but it creates an intriguing coupling between the lowest and highest Buxton Indexes in the organization. The hope would be that the PMs would nominate people who would get it , in the sense that it takes someone who has been in the trenches to get what it's like to be there. Board member election could also be a mechanism to get long-term PM buy-in despite short-term tenures. Either "graduated" PMs could participate in every board member selection or there could be a single board position devoted to representing alumni that only alumni can select. More broadly, employee ownership could enable a DARPA-riff to align long-term incentives.

The PMs" check on the director could also resemble the American system, where the Executive Branch has veto power over the Legislative Branch. Perhaps the PMs should have veto power over both proposed rule changes and (especially) new PMs. Implementing veto power within a group of people is tricky because it could easily lead to politics with single PMs trying to convince the others to go along with them.

Avoiding deadlock

Deadlock is the primary failure mode of an organization with a robust system of checks and balances. The obvious places in this scheme that seem most deadlock-prone are the PMs" veto power and the writing-based decision-making. You could imagine a situation where the PMs veto literally every rule change and potential new PM to try to force the director to do something. Similarly, you could also imagine a situation where everybody uses written precedent and the constitution to browbeat and block one another instead of talking and trusting.

To the former case, there could be a check on this check, like enabling an agreement between the director and the board to overturn a veto. To the latter case, one could suggest something like an "Ask forgiveness, not permission clause," that enables rule-breaking actions if they have good outcomes. Both of these might be fine ideas, and there may be other similar fixes, but there are limitations to this type of thinking.

At the end of the day, you cannot create a set of rules that will guarantee that a group of people will work together in a way that produces high-variance results over many organizational generations. Effective action will always depend on trust and communication. There are several structural pieces that can make this trust and communication more likely : keeping the organization small, maintaining a precise mission, and filling all positions with excellent, diligent, and applied people. However, all structural components will be worthless if the people in the organization don't commit to constantly maintaining the organization in the same way you maintain a building. Intentionality and trust are unavoidable!

Employee ownership could enable a DARPA-riff to align long-term incentives

A DARPA-riff needs to be obsessed with program managers. Unfortunately, many of the attributes that make people excellent PMs also make them good for many other roles; people who are potential PMs have a lot of options. Unlike DARPA, a DARPA-riff doesn't offer people a way to serve their country, and at least in the early days, you won't be able to pay as much as a tech or finance job.

This heavy reliance on in-demand people means that it's important to think seriously about why people would take up the role and how to make sure that their incentives are aligned with the organization's. There are many ways a DARPA-riff could structurally address this question; "employee ownership" might go a long way toward encouraging everybody involved in the enterprise to work towards its long-term success. Of course, that term is incredibly vague, so let's break it down and think about what implementing it might look like.

Employee ownership via economic stake

One sense of employee ownership is to give everybody a stake in any potential economic upside. While a DARPA-riff probably can't be profitable overall , that doesn't necessarily mean there can't be an economic upside for employees.

It's likely that a DARPA-riff will eventually spin out companies. If it does, it could potentially retain shares in those companies via a for-profit entity. Employees could have shares of this entity. The shares could act as a smoothing function on the amount of value different PMs capture and create buy-in to the organization's long-term success instead of only a PM's specific program. Anecdotally, even a small number of shares in Entrepreneur First's global fund (which, rationally, most people realized was not going to be a life-changing amount of money) created a sense of caring about the organization and its long-term outcome.

The best way to handle liquidity in a for-profit DARPA-riff subsidiary is still an open question. If employees have shares in a for-profit subsidiary, somehow those shares need to turn into cash eventually. The subsidiary could go public, but that's a bad idea for too many reasons to get into here. Another option would be to have it be a fixed-life fund similar to a PE or VC fund β€” this seems to create misaligned incentives with creating long-term value. Both traditional options being off the table means that the situation isn't hopeless, but it does need more work.

The first requirement that Nonprofits must meet to maintain 501(3)(c) status might clash with an employee pool: "Organizations that apply for tax-exempt status cannot serve the private interests, or private benefit, of any individual or organization besides itself past an insubstantial degree." This requirement is probably why OpenAI is structured so that all the employees are employees of the for-profit subsidiary. A DARPA-riff could do something similar, with the for-profit subsidiary employing almost everybody and contracting them to a Nonprofit entity.

Regardless of how it's done, it's important that any employee value-capture mechanism ignores how much value those employees themselves captured. Specifically, I'm worried about incentives that push people to work on programs that they think can create more-certain capturable value instead of less-certain (but potentially massive) uncapturable value.

There will be unavoidable inequality between the amount of value different PMs capture. Some programs will probably lead to successful companies; the people who do the work to get the company off the ground will inevitably reap the lion's share of the rewards. There is so much more to starting a successful company than the technology it's built around, so it seems reasonable that a significant chunk of its value should be captured by people who build the company instead of just doing the research. Some programs will yield complete duds. Some PMs will do work that leads to highly paid consulting gigs or nifty jobs. Some programs will create massive value that is impossible to capture. It's impossible for an employee value-capture mechanism to eliminate these inequalities (nor should it), but it should attempt to buffer them.

My model of monetary compensation is that for most people 231 it's not a strict matter of "More is better," but that there is a threshold that feels "fair" above which other incentives matter much more.

Employee ownership via control

In addition to economic stakes, people tend to feel more invested in the long-term success of an institution if they have a voice in its direction.

The most prominent way that organizations implement employee ownership is through the co-op model. I honestly could not find any great resources on how co-ops work. The best I could do is this Ohio State University site . If you know of any better ones, please let me know! As gross oversimplification: Instead of a co-op having a management team who answers to a board, co-op employees are the management team and elect representatives who liaise with the board. There's something emotionally appealing in the idea of a DARPA-riff as a "research collective."

A DARPA-riff likely can't adopt a co-op model out of whole cloth; co-ops tend to be organizations that sell concrete outputs on relatively short time scales, like farms and retail stores. However, the idea of PMs comprising the Executive Branch in a constitutional system is shockingly similar to a co-op. In both cases, the "members" select who will be on the board. The difference is that the constitutional model has three separate branches while co-ops have two. I suspect this third branch (the director/Legislative Branch) is important for dealing with longer time scales and more nebulosity than normal co-ops.

A bit of weirdness for control-type ownership pops up because of PMs" short tenures.

If PMs don't feel a long-term connection with the DARPA-riff, their level of autonomy will easily allow them to act in ways that are good for them but bad for the organization. This could look like taking on lower-risk programs so they're likely to have a win under their belt that they can leverage later in their career; or (if the PMs have strong control-type ownership) pushing raises that would give the organization far less runway. There are many actions that are not overtly bad, like embezzling, but if they were widespread, it would quickly bring the organization to its knees. Short tenures have the potential to amplify this sort of problem.

Universities are a good case study in creating a connection between an institution and short-tenured individuals. Despite being primarily composed of students who will be there for ~5 years (with high variance), universities both manage to maintain a stable intergenerational culture and convince alumni to care about the institution's long-term health after they graduate. This example makes it worthwhile to ask, "How are universities so institutionally and culturally stable?" One possibility to create long-term buy-in is to have a board member who is explicitly a representative for "graduated" PMs, in the same way that universities often have an alumni representative as part of their governance.

A DARPA-riff could establish sales channels for frontier tech

There is nothing more difficult to take in hand, more perilous to conduct or more uncertain in its success, than to take the lead in the new order of things; because the innovator has for enemies all those who have done well under the old conditions, and lukewarm defenders in those who may do well under the new.

β€”Machiavelli, The Prince

Another important organizational experiment is to figure out better ways to get new types of technology out into the world.

Frontier technology has bespoke sales channels. People trying to get new technology out into the world constantly need to do some combination of shoving it into ill-fitting but established channels ("We're going to sell this jetpack like SaaS software!") or creating a new way of selling from scratch. The latter introduces a whole new failure point for the technology and sometimes requires as much inventiveness as creating the technology itself. Making this process less harrowing would have massive impact.

Speculatively, a DARPA-riff may be able to address new technology's problematic dispersion-related uncertainty through institutional knowledge accumulation, credibility, and ongoing relationships.

Knowledge accumulation

Over the years, the startup world has built up cultural wisdom about how to sell software. Could the same thing happen for the wildly different technologies that might come out of DARPA-like programs? A general-purpose telerobotic platform is incredibly different from a molecular factory, and they both look nothing like a muon-catalyzed fusion prototype.

Despite massive technology differences, I suspect that a DARPA-riff could accumulate institutional pattern-matching for disperate technologies if they explicitly set out to do so. This hunch is based in large part on personal experience trying to help dozens of "deep tech" startups off the ground. There were hints of replicable patterns in building out successful sales channels in everything from hydrogen filters to grocery-store robots. Truthfully, I didn't spend enough time doing it to pull on that thread and investigate where it went.

Institutional credibility

Credibility matters in technology diffusion. People (and thus organizations too) are more willing to at least try something they're dubious of if it has a name they trust behind it. Of course, it's critical that the technology work well! But credibility can be that initial foot in the door. In the same way that individual academic labs can gain credibility from the university as a whole, individual programs and people could lean on a DARPA-riff's established organizational reputation.

Ongoing relationships

Technology diffusion inevitably depends on many other organizations: manufacturers, regulators, resellers, advertisers ... the list goes on. And people like to work with people they've worked with before. One big reason people tend to bet on industry insiders launching new ventures is because of the assumption that their existing relationships will reduce friction and make them more likely to succeed. At the same time, new technological paradigms often come from outsiders. What might look like a nefarious plot to suppress change 233 can also be explained by outsiders not having the right relationships.

It might be possible to circumvent this problem by maintaining relationships with people in a wide array of other organizations at the umbrella-organization level. The alternative would be to force each program to develop new relationships or to find someone who has them on top of technical work. Even more speculatively, these relationships could be codified in actual contracts where external organizations (manufacturers or distributors) are part of a consortium that gets first crack at program outputs, similar to the MIT Media Lab's model.

This is one of those ideas that can sound good on paper but will be incredibly hard in practice. ARPA-E has an entire tech-to-market team and still has a mixed track record.

R&D incentivization SPAC

I'm allowed to have one part of the speculation section that's just pure wild speculation, right? OK, here goes: It might be possible to create a SPAC In a grossly oversimplified nutshell, SPACs (special purpose acquisition companies) are publicly listed shell companies that merge with private companies, effectively taking them public without an IPO. that is designed to incentivize getting technology past a goalpost.

Normally, SPACs either have a fairly broad mandate ("Find a high-potential tech company") or are created in order to take a specific company public. What if instead the SPACs mandate was to go after a specific set of technological milestones? Say, for example, the ability to create an arbitrary chemical reaction at a specific site faster than a given rate with precision to a specific number of nanometers (which would be, broadly, the specs for a company on the way toward atomically precise manufacturing).

In effect, an R&D incentivization SPAC (RDISPAC just rolls off the tongue, right?) could act like a non-government advanced market commitment for a technology. Advanced market commitments are the government saying, in effect, "If you create something that meets these specifications, we guarantee we will buy N of them for $X apiece." Anton Howes has a good Twitter thread about advanced market commitments here . The most famous advanced market commitment in recent memory is the US government's approach to COVID-19 vaccines. Of course, an RDISPAC would differ from an advanced market commitment because investment doesn't automatically translate to customers the way an advanced market commitment does.

The milestones that a SPAC is looking for would need to be very carefully considered. The best technologies don't always win, so there needs to be a strong argument that technical capabilities will translate into a long-term profitable business. Drug companies get around this problem because it's basically guaranteed that if you create a drug that gets FDA approval for a certain set of conditions, insurance companies will pay for it. However, in any other case, new technology has bespoke sales channels. Instead of a fairly legible process, creating sales channels for something nobody has seen before requires almost magical persuasion. One of the reasons why VCs (accurately) care so much about a startup's founding team is because much of a company's success has nothing to do with the technology and everything to do with sales and market creation. See " Productive Uncertainty ." It seems like an open question how to both argue that a technology-based SPAC is a good investment and have its acquisition conditions be based only on technical milestones. Additionally, the cash injection from the SPAC needs to be able to get the technology to a place where you're seeing fairly continuous business improvement. If the SPAC acquires a technology company and the share price falls, it's unlikely that you'll be able to raise any more money.

If we talk about it in terms of technology readiness levels (TRLs), See a more detailed description of technology readiness levels here . an RDISPAC could target either 3 (proof of concept), 6 (prototype in a relevant environment), or 8 (production version in a real environment). If the RDISPAC were targeting TRL 3 or 6, the technology would actually skip being a VC-funded startup. If the RDSPAC targeted TRL 8, you would still need to raise private funds and build a business, but the existence of the SPAC, as a clear exit option, would hopefully make it easier to raise funds.

RDISPACs could contribute to a healthier technology creation ecosystem. The organization that is doing the work to get technology projects off the ground and help fund them initially, like a DARPA-riff, could manage the SPAC as well. We've already seen a few technology-focused VC firms, like Lux Capital, go down this route. The advantage of a DARPA-riff helping manage a SPAC would be that management fees could go directly toward creating more technology. Running both the beginning and end of the pipeline may enable a "closed loop" technology development system, where the organization helping germinate the technology can capture some of its value without taking deadweight equity or licensing fees.

Of course, the closed-loop scheme could potentially incentivize fraud! It's important to think about fraud upfront because, in addition to being bad in and of itself, it could poison the whole mechanism, even for honest actors. Precise, externally verifiable acquisition conditions could both prevent fraud and create alignment between investors and organizations shooting for the target. In a way, precise acquisition conditions can focus the conversation around how valuable it could be if technology with a certain capability existed. It's entirely my bias, but these conversations would further increase the value of precise, understandable roadmaps.

Of course, there are many technologies whose values were unknown a priori (personal computers, cars, etc.), so RDISPACs are not a silver bullets.

There is obviously a horde of unanswered questions. Some fun ones to think about might include:

  • Is there a way to test public appetite for something like this?
  • Publicly owned R&D assets have traditionally not done well β€” people are fine buying and holding when something is low volatility, but R&D tends to be high volatility. Is there a way around this?
  • What are the conditions on SPAC investments? There is still tons of business risk even if you hit technological milestones, so this would be much higher risk than most things on the market.
  • How can you both argue that a technology-based SPAC is a good investment and have its acquisition conditions be based only on technical milestones? Speculatively, could the RDISPAC management also do the legwork to line up advanced market commitments from governments or companies?

Again, this is wild speculation on a hype-filled trend. Like all the other speculations, it's hard to be sure that it will work, but it's the sort of thing that's worth thinking about.

Part III: The Institute for Creative Technology - How I Propose to Navigate the Maze

The men preferred to think they worked not in a laboratory but in what Kelly once called "an institute of creative technology." This description aimed to inform the world that the line between the art and science of what Bell scientists did wasn't always distinct. Moreover, while many of Kelly's colleagues might have been eccentrics, few were dreamers in the less flattering sense of the word. They were paid for their imaginative abilities. But they were also paid for working within a culture, and within an institution, where the very point of new ideas was to make them into new things.

β€” Jon Gertner, The Idea Factory

Knowing things about the maze is worthless if you don't use that knowledge to chart a path. But as soon as you discover that what you thought would be a valid turn is in fact a dead end, the entire path needs to be rejiggered! As a result, this is weirdly both the most important and the most transient part of the piece!

In this part, I dig into the specifics of what I (and perhaps, with your help, we ) are setting out to do to build Private ARPA (PARPA). If Part II was a description of the junctions that any maze adventurer could face, Part III is the path that I expect my thread to trace.

I will first lay out the organizational structures that I suspect will best dip, doge, duck, and dive between the constraints we explored in Part II. I'll then lay out a series of nested hypotheses that effectively make up the organization's roadmap. The notion is that "testing" each hypothesis will progressively de-risk the giant spiky ball of assumptions underlying this whole scheme. These hypotheses will comprise three major phases in the organization's development. I'll outline these phases and the conditions for phase shifts.

Some of you have probably been asking, "Yes, but what programs will you actually work on ??" this whole time. Your appetite will finally be sated! In this part, I'll sketch some potential programs that the organization could undertake.

Most people who enter a labyrinth β€” even those with a plan β€” don't survive. With that in mind, I'll close with a glance into the abyss and outline as explicitly as I can why this whole adventure could fail and what success could look like. My hope is that such an analysis will maximize both the chances of success and what we can learn in the unfortunate case of failure.

Precise visions are more likely to happen

A striking through-line that connects ambitious and successful technology programs from SpaceX to PARC (and ARPA computing programs before that) is that they were organized either explicitly or implicitly around a precise vision of the future. 238 These precise visions both act like a filter for likely-to-succeed programs and contribute directly to that success.

The causal relationship between precise visions and success is fairly intuitive. A precise vision acts as a coordinating mechanism that enables a large group of people to agree on what things they are working toward and, perhaps more importantly, what they are not working toward. Just as mythic rowers are useless without the coordination of a drumbeat, any compelling vision will generate action, but if it's imprecise, the energy will quickly dissipate. It's the difference between rocket fuel creating a fireball and delivering a payload to orbit. If people can see the specific actions that they can do now in order to move toward the vision, it's comparatively easy for them to start doing them. However, most visions are abstract and fuzzy, which leads to reactions along the lines of, "Somebody should do something!" "Pass a law!" or "It sure would be nice if ..." Legibility enables action!

I suspect that precise visions are also a filter for programs that are more likely to be successful. You could think of the vision like a test against reality. Do we understand the thing well enough to execute on it? If no, it's less likely to be feasible and may need more work before a program is likely to succeed. Of course, if you can precisely say what that pre-work is, you've bootstrapped your way to a (different) precise program. Precision produces payoffs!

This litmus test doesn't limit you to just incremental changes either β€” Vannevar Bush's essay "As We May Think" See " As We May Think " (uses up one of three free articles at The Atlantic). painted a precise vision of a thinking tool that was a massive paradigm shift away from anything that had existed before and yet precisely described many aspects of computers we'd recognize today.

PARPA's path through the maze is a series of nested hypotheses

A validated hypothesis is like getting to a junction you expected to be there, turning in the direction you expected to turn, and not dying.

Bundled together, PARPA's path through the maze looks like:

1. Create and stress-test unintuitive research programs in a systematic (and therefore repeatable) way.

2. Use that credibility to run a handful of research programs and produce results that wouldn't happen otherwise.

3. Use that credibility to run more research programs and help them "graduate" to effective next steps.

4. Make the entire cycle eventually-autocatylizing by plowing windfalls into an endowment.

We can transform these steps into real action by making explicit the hypotheses each step entails. Each of these hypotheses is made of several constituent hypotheses. (And those are made of even smaller hypotheses until you get to things like, "If I send an email to Professor So-and-So, we will have a meeting and they will be able to point me to two other people to talk to ..." but I will leave that level of detail to your imagination.) I'll present an overview below (with numbers and letters so we can refer to specific hypotheses) and then dig into each one.

  1. It's possible to design programs in a systematic (and therefore repeatable) way .
    1. It's possible to find people who want to do pieces of work that would not happen otherwise.
    2. There exist several areas that could possibly yield results (defined loosely) in 3–5 years (given steady work).
    3. For each potential program, it's possible to come up with a set of small experiments that could further confirm or deny its feasibility within 12–24 months and ~$1M scale.
    4. It's possible to get people to undertake seedling experiments.
    5. Accomplishing 1a→1d will involve a combination of one-on-one conversations driven by reading papers, finding gaps, reaching out to people, and holding small, intensive workshops.
    6. It's possible to find people who are excited to be PMs and actually do 1a→1e.
    7. It's possible to systematize this process.
  2. It's possible to execute on these programs in a way that relaxes academic/startup constraints.
    1. It will be possible to coordinate several research projects toward a coherent goal.
    2. The early pieces of work will be done by some combination of academic labs, contract R&D orgs, independent researchers, and possibly people within corporate R&D who are able to do work for grants.
    3. People will be willing to shift their organizational affiliations to an exploratory program organization as the program goes on.
  3. It's possible to "graduate" these programs in a way that gives them a life of their own.
    1. During the programs themselves, it will be possible to do some of the pre-work to figure out the best way to graduate technology in order to maximize its beneficial impact on the world.
    2. At least some of the people who have been working on the program will want to carry it forward in some form.
    3. Some of the technology will make sense as a company, some of it will make sense as a nonprofit, some of it will make sense as a licensed technology, and some of it will make sense as open-source.
  4. It's possible for this entire cycle to eventually become autocatalytic.
    1. An early (non-monetary) component of autocatalysis is a community that generates good inbound programs.
    2. 'Pseudo-autocatalysis" is a state where the organization is getting enough consistent revenue through some combination of donations, spin-offs, and other sources, like licensing and consulting, that it can continue to run multiple programs assuming those revenue sources continue.
    3. Full autocatalysis can only happen by building up an endowment.

I'll walk through each of these in as much detail as possible. Fair warning: We'll quickly reach the limits of making research legible upfront. So many things need to be figured out on the fly, and as a result, the details of these hypotheses are going to read much more like working notes than a polished piece. Later hypotheses get more fuzzy because the farther you go in time, the more paths can fork. Many of the details about hypotheses sound like a litany of ways that it could go wrong β€” alas, this is the nature of these experimental things.

It's possible to systematically design programs

The first big question that any pragmatic person asks about PARPA is, "So, what are you working on?" 240 Building a process to consistently and precisely generate answers to that question is PARPA's first major task.

"Figuring out what to work on" (or worse, figuring out how to figure out what to work on) as a first major step may sound a bit silly (and indeed, it feels a bit silly to write it). Startups are generally created to go after a specific problem or opportunity, so it's a big red flag if they don't know what they're working on from day one. 241 Conversely, actively "figuring out what to work on" is also a waste of time for most research funding organizations; once they've settled on a broad area, their modus operandi is to solicit and judge applications.

In both of these situations, though, the "context" of work is roughly fixed and well established. People have patterns to match. A key reason for PARPA's existence is to enable work that's not being done because it doesn't fall into those well-established contexts. Good PARPA programs will lurk in the shadows of counterfactuals, and counterfactuals are hard. Our job, then, is not just figuring out what to work on but three coupled questions: What things would be enabled by a new context, what is that context, and can PARPA create it? Program design will require answering all three in a way that resembles the final step of solving a blacksmith's puzzle β€” each answer depends on all the others.

To give you a flavor of some of the questions we'll need to tackle in the process of figuring out what to work on: Is it a matter of coordinating multiple pieces of a system? Creating collaborations between disciplines? Prompting aggressive ideas that researchers aren't even thinking because they wouldn't normally be funded? Or does the thing not exist because it's actually just violating some laws of physics? What experiments could be done to test the answers to these questions?

Another reason figuring out what to work on is not straightforward is that PARPA is especially susceptible to the chicken-and-egg situation facing any new institution: We can't be sure that we can work on something until we know who will be working on it, and people are hesitant to agree to work on something until the organization declares that it's working on it. We can't honestly declare that we're working on something until we at least have strong suspicions about who will be working on it. Unlike most startups that base their plans on hiring fairly fungible roles β€” "a software engineer" or "a data scientist" 242 β€” PARPA programs will hinge on working with people who have knowledge and skills that only exist in a few minds around the world. Many ambitious proposals start with "Someone should do this crazy ambitious thing" but never actually specify who is both qualified and willing to do it. Finding those people and building trust relationships with them will be a project in itself . Who is open to participating will shape the programs PARPA should undertake.

I've already begun this process for a few possible programs, and frankly, it is a full-time job in and of itself.

This chicken-and-egg situation will hopefully change once we have enough institutional momentum that we can count on inbounds, but even DARPA PMs tend to get precommitments from researchers to respond to calls for proposals before they launch programs.

Finally, the entire process needs to be repeatable. Creating the initial programs will undoubtedly be ad-hoc and a bit of a mess, but in order for PARPA to be able to consistently create programs in the future, it will be critical to spend time and effort paying attention to what works, what doesn't, and what could be systematized.

It's possible to find people who want to do pieces of work that would not happen otherwise

Most people don't advertise the fact that they want to go after slightly crazy research that requires resources or collaborators that aren't already at their disposal. This is doubly true if they actually have the skill to pull it off. 243 There are exceptions, of course, but most career-focused researchers file overly ambitious ideas away "for later." Often these ideas are buried so deep that they need prompting and trust to even talk about them out loud. 244

A big part of the PARPA's success depends on our ability to find these people. It will be a harder task than it might seem, especially without a track record. While doing a few pieces of preliminary program design, I've found that the people who are excited about ambitious technical ideas often aren't in a position to execute on those ideas; either because they don't have the technical expertise 245 or they're in a long-term position that precludes them from doing the work. Conversely, the people who on paper are at the cutting edge of a field tend to have gotten there by being laser-focused on a specific academic research agenda that can proceed methodically using the resources available to a single lab. This self-selected group is often distinctly unexcited by larger jumps that would involve combining their research with other disciplines.

Not all hope is lost! I have come across several people who do seem to have a magical blend of technical skills and excitement about ambitious possibilities that might be one step beyond what the consensus thinks is possible. These people tend to be postdocs, grad students, and technically trained people who have left academia. So the "right" people do exist β€” the challenge is to figure out how to find them consistently and bridge the gap between "intrigued" and "on board.'

The people who would want to do early program work tend to be postdocs, grad students, and technically trained people who have left academia

After talking to dozens of researchers in the process of poking program possibilities, I've noticed a pattern. Tenured professors are happy to talk about the next step suggested by a specific paper and fuzzy long-term ideas, but postdocs, grad students, and technically trained people who have left academia ('tenure-trackless folks') are the ones who have the precise ambitious ideas that are critical for a solutions R&D program. It's frustrating to ask the point of contact for an exciting paper (who is usually the most senior coauthor who nine times out of 10 is the professor) about what possibilities the paper opens up only to hear a list of more-of-the-same kinds of experiments that are well within their grasp. If you can dig up the contact info for the tenure-trackless folks on the paper, on the other hand, you're often rewarded with, "Well, if we could simulate this better, we'd be able to ..." or, "If we could work with some physicists, we could ..."

This response pattern makes sense: Professors tend to become successful by finding a speciality and becoming its master through deliberate, incremental work. This specialization makes them great at acquiring grants ("This person wants to do this feasible thing that nobody else in the world can do!") but pushes them into a mode where they have clear boundaries between the feasible within their realm of control and the infeasible outside of it. People with very little research experience tend to be the opposite: full of grand ideas, but with no idea how to implement them. Tenure-trackless folks are able to walk the middle way between the two extremes.

Another reason to seek out tenure-trackless folks is that they are (by definition) less tied to the traditional academic career path. So, if a program ends up being successful, there will be a higher chance that they'll be open to "graduating" with it to whatever form makes the most sense β€” whether it is a startup, nonprofit, or some kind of corporate absorption. Intellectual continuity is critical for a graduated program's eventual success in the real world.

Testing this hypothesis will entail deliberately skewing conversations and workshops toward tenure-trackless folks. This skew is tricky for two reasons. First, the person that people associate with an area of interest is usually a professor. Professor obsession makes it hard to find the high-quality tenure-trackless folks in the first place, because one of the best tactics to find your way to interesting people is through recommendations. Second, tenure-trackless folks often don't have the same access to labs and equipment as professors, so working with them on externalized research will present extra challenges.

The focus on tenure-trackless folks should not be exclusive by any stretch of the imagination. There are tenured professors who want to use their tenure's freedom to its full extent and sometimes still do benchwork. There are high-school dropouts who learned to build bioreactors in their basements. However, I suspect those people will be such rarefied outliers that the bulk of scarce resources will be better spent cultivating tenure-trackless folks.

The pieces of work in a PARPA program will tend to be things that people think can't get through a grant committee or require some sort of collaboration that isn't available to them

PARPA needs to nail down early the type of work that it's enabling. There are two opposing traps we could potentially fall into: On one side is supporting work that would happen regardless, and on the other side is supporting work that is actually impossible. The delineation is clear as mud; there are even things that would happen regardless and are actually impossible. This nebulosity means that instead of rigid classification systems, we'll need to focus on developing heuristics.

I have a hunch that there are (at least) two heuristics for the type of work that falls into the sweet spot of "possible but not incentivized': work that people suspect wouldn't be able to get through a grant committee, and work that would require some sort of weird collaboration. Both of these cases tend to fall into mental blind spots: Instead of a nagging pain, they're the sort of thing where you think, "That would be nice," but then forget about it. Part of PARPA's role is to tease out those discarded ideas.

Work might not be able to get through a grant committee for several reasons: It doesn't fit into a neat bucket; it isn't directly related to research that the performer has done before; 246 or it just doesn't have strong evidence that it will succeed.

The sort of work that might require a nonexistent collaboration is hard to generalize. An example might be a molecular-level process that a chemistry group wants to implement, but the time it takes to synthesize and the range of possible outcomes makes trial-and-error experiments infeasible. A machine-learning-driven simulation could narrow down the search space enough to make trial-and-error in the constrained search space feasible, but the chemistry group has nobody with the expertise to build the simulation. At the same time, the simulation folks have nobody with the nuanced experience with chemistry to help make the simulations they're building actually useful. PARPA could fund both groups to work together and help coordinate between them.

Frontier-pushing technical people will be willing to work with a new organization

Even if it's possible to find people who want to do pieces of work that would not happen otherwise , there is a big gap between "interested" and "on board." People will happily have conversations and spitball ideas; actually sitting down and doing work is an entirely different beast. This gap means that another hypothesis PARPA needs to validate early on is that we will be able to get researchers to work with us.

A big part of working with research is the ability to fund the research at all, which is what makes this hypothesis one of those experiments that can only be done in the context of an organization. However, money is necessary but nowhere near sufficient to get people to work with you. People need to be excited about the work; it will inevitably require both creativity and persistence in spades. We can't go all in on "Be excited! Pursue your passion!" For any single project in the program because eventually the different projects need to converge. Finding this balance consistently will be hard!

Some tactics that we can test to "onboard" collaborators include: small workshops of high-potential possible performers, spending a lot of work building trust with individual researchers, Warren Weaver, the Rockefeller Foundation program officer who funded early genetics work, expands on this point in his notes for other program officers . and working to build a long-term community that will continue to be valuable to researchers after any specific project.

There exist several areas that could possibly yield results (defined loosely) in 3–5 years (given steady work)

PARPA's success depends on creating several programs in the "sweet spot" where they'll yield tangible results in 3–5 years. "Tangible" here doesn't necessarily mean a product, per se, but an artifact that inspires confidence in people outside of the organization. This constraint is purely pragmatic β€” realistically, even people who are excited about PARPA's potential (hopefully you, dear reader) will lose enthusiasm if the organization doesn't make some sort of visible progress over several years. As the organization builds more trust over time, it will be able to go after longer-term programs and work on promising projects for "as long as it takes," but the path dependence is important.

This plan rests on the hypothesis that the sweet spot even exists. It could be the case that solutions R&D programs that could show results in 3–5 years are uninspiring and/or are already being tacked for any number of reasons β€” a frothy VC market, unusually prescient grant allocators, actual DARPA, etc. This is where program design plays an important role: It's important not only to have reasons to believe that a program will be successful but to have reasons to believe early on that there's a chance that success will happen on a useful time scale. The two specific programs that we have been digging at so far are general-purpose telerobotics and first steps on what would be a series of programs toward atomically precise manufacturing. We're open to suggestions!

For each potential PARPA program, it's possible to come up with a set of small experiments that could further confirm or deny its feasibility within 12–24 months and ~$1M scale

DARPA PMs use seedling projects to "acid test" the riskiest pieces of a program idea. See the section " DARPA PMs use seedling projects to "acid test" the riskiest pieces of a program idea " from "Why Does DARPA Work?" I'm confident that PARPA will be able to do something similar for our programs, but it's still a hypothesis we need to explicitly test. It is extremely hard to call out in advance which pieces of evidence would compellingly suggest that a crazy idea is at least possible.

Part of de-risking this hypothesis is frankly just a learning process about what makes a good seedling project. After studying examples of past DARPA seedling programs, some potential heuristics are:

  • Good seedling projects specifically go after the reasons that everybody says that something won't work. Their goal isn't to make it work, but to at least show that the reason why it won't work isn't the game-ender that it at first appears to be. For this approach to work, it's critical to precisely pin down both what won't work and why experts assert that's the case.
  • The tagline will either sound incredibly silly ("How memes become reality") or incomprehensible ("Augmented Reality-based Collaborative and Corroborative Collection"). Speculatively, this heuristic might work because seedlings need to either be poking at a broad hunch (that it might be possible for memes to become reality) or a specific interesting technical thing that you suspect could become significant.

I suspect the line between success and failure in seedling projects will often be fuzzy. This nebulosity is why developing trust with performers will be critical. Human judgment will be unavoidable in deciding whether the seedling experiments provide enough evidence to launch a full program. Another possible frame for the seedling programs is that they serve as a trust-building "trial" period. Think of internships, or how some companies set it up so that employees and the company can both choose to part ways after a few months.

Below are some top-of-mind examples The last four are directly from Adam Marblestone. of speculative seedling projects to prime your intuition pump. They might not be feasible for many reasons!

  • Showing that it might be possible to get muons to have a higher replication rate in a fusion reaction.
  • Doing a study on what the design for a broadly applicable robot specifically designed for telerobotics work might look like.
  • Experimenting with the binding constraints on scaling up carbon-free cement.
  • Testing AlphaFold in a closed loop with specified properties for the blocks that a 3D-protein printer would use.
  • Showing that you can make a nanoscale breadboard by applying implosion fabrication to a DNA microarray.
  • Showing that temperature-hardened electronics and communications developed for space missions could withstand the conditions involved in drilling 20 km into the Earth for geothermal energy.
  • Designing a MEMS device that could polish or sharpen its own features after fabrication.
  • Prototyping a small sensor that could extract DNA from muddy water while harvesting the mud as a biofuel and allowing for self-sterilization and cleaning.

It's possible to get people to undertake seedling experiments

An obvious but important challenge is to bridge the gap between potential performers being "interested" and actually taking action. How do we shift the people we found while testing the hypothesis that "It's possible to find people who want to do things that would not happen otherwise" from interest to action? It's one thing to find people who have both the ambition and the skills to undertake things and another to actually get them to spend the time undertaking them!

This is where having money and an organization is actually important. At some point we need to be able to say, "We'll fund the work to explore this thing." Does there need to be a contract? What sort of agreement does it look like? Can we work directly with the tenure-trackless folks or will we be forced to go through a professor or university bureaucracy? Could we "hire" someone for an "internship" to do seedling projects? There are fractal questions that will only be resolved by just doing the thing.

Accomplishing hypotheses 1a β†’ 1d will require a combination of gumshoeing and workshops

Finding people and promising areas, figuring out the experiments they could do to poke at binding constraints, and then pulling everything together so those experiments happen will require a lot of fuzzy "people-wrangling." If you write down what the work I would call "gumshoeing" entails β€” lots of emails, talking to people, following up, connecting, circling back, negotiating β€” it certainly deserves the uncomfortable side-eye it gets from people (like me) who like concrete, actionable plans. Doing those things can easily lead nowhere if done poorly. Hopefully, by explicitly calling out the possibility, we can avoid that trap, but it remains a deeply unsatisfying answer.

Workshops are a systemized way of people-wrangling

DARPA program managers often hold small workshops of experts as part of their program design process. See the section " A large part of a DARPA program manager's job is focused network building " from "Why Does DARPA Work?" Running a series of these workshops might be a small, actionable place to start PARPA.

I suspect that a big part of starting and testing PARPA's viability is to design sufficiently precise programs : External researchers need to believe the projects in the program are a convincing use of their time, external funders need to be willing to provide the money to start executing on those programs, and we need to believe that they actually have a chance of unlocking something amazing if they're successful. 251

One way to start designing programs is to run a series of workshops where a handful people at the edge of a discipline with different backgrounds get together to riff on one another, explore, and argue their way toward a clear picture of the edge of possibility.

What would a workshop look like concretely?

Imagine 5–7 people who understand the edge of a discipline but are fringey in one way or another getting together in person in a big whiteboard-filled house in the woods somewhere with relatively easy access to an airport. The participants would spend a week digging into the precise problems in areas like, "Why don't we have black-box factories?" "How could we grow infrastructure like plants?" "How far could we push our ability to do positionally-controlled chemistry?" with the goal of establishing what's possible in a 2–5 year time frame that's not being worked on, precisely why not, and what work would need to happen in order to get there.

Admittedly, it's a big ask for people to take a week out of their lives. Unfortunately, less than a week is probably insufficient. It takes people a few days to get comfortable with one another to the point where they're willing to dig into out-there ideas. It might be possible to boost the comfort level beforehand with digital tools, but I'm skeptical.

Workshops would ideally produce several concrete outputs:

  • A list of preliminary seedling projects that could act as go/no-go experiments for a larger program, along with who should be doing them.
  • Answers to all of the questions in the Heilmeier Catechism, or precise reasons why the answer is unknown or nebulous (and the project you would need to do to firm it up).
  • A "roadmap" of what would happen in a full program if the seedling projects pan out.
  • A list of key people in an area to loop in on the project.

Optimistically, after running a few workshops, the participants could form the core of a larger community. This group would ideally serve two purposes: It would help people who want to push the edge of their fields find overlapping and complementary people In Reinventing Discovery , Michael Nielsen elegantly describes this process as "designed serendipity." and provide a pool of people in PARPA's orbit who could help generate program ideas, act as contractors, and perhaps become PMs or performers. As a proof point, Ink & Switch seems to have pursued this strategy successfully!

Pros and cons of the hub-and-spoke model of program design

The alternative to workshops would be for the program manager to talk to a slew of experts directly and do the synthesis themselves. This is the hub-and-spoke model of program design. It has the PM as the hub in the middle, doing the majority of the talking with the experts and perhaps connecting them as needed. This approach has pros and cons. The pros are that a PM will be maximally bought into a program entirely of their own creation and the idea will be maximally coherent. Committees tend to lead to median results, and it's easy for workshops to devolve into committee thinking.

On the other hand, the hub-and-spoke model requires the PM to figure out all the right questions to ask or play the go-between for different experts. The hub-and-spoke method might be ideal when a PM comes in with a strong hypothesis about the program and expertise in the area. I might be able to do this for a simulation- or robotics-based program, but would be unable to do it for something in biology or materials.

It seems important for PARPA's initial programs to be relatively uncorrelated. Programs designed via the hub-and-spoke method by the same PM will be more strongly correlated with one another than via the workshop method. Early on, we won't have very many PMs, which could exacerbate the correlation. These facts suggest that while it's worthwhile to pursue both strategies, the potential pros of the workshop method and the potential downsides of the hub-and-spoke method mean that PARPA should lean more heavily on workshops early in its life.

It's possible to find people who are both willing and capable to be program managers

Like any DARPA-riff , PARPA's success or failure will hinge on our ability to work with amazing program managers. It's not a given that we'll be able to find the right people and persuade them to work with us. Pickiness will abound on both sides: People who would be good PMs have many options in life; at the same time, PARPA needs to be discerning about who becomes PMs because of the trust and responsibility that they must shoulder.

Given these challenges, how do we propose to find PMs and why will they join?

A chunk of this hypothesis is based on confidence that the frustratingly vague "people-wrangling" that also goes into program design will yield fruit. "I suspect that if I try really hard I will succeed." This hypothesis is not entirely based on hubris, though β€” below are some more precise hunches about where to find PMs and what will convince them to forgo other options:

  • The same tenure-trackless folks who might make good performers may also make good PMs. Performers often become PMs at actual DARPA.
  • People who are thinking about starting companies (or started and stopped) as the best of bad options for enabling a technology would be good PMs. Some subset of people who start startups are doing it not because they want to build a business but because it seems like the best way to get a technology into the world. In some of those cases, a PARPA program would be far more effective than a startup.
  • While we won't be able to pay as much as a big tech company, I suspect that the people who would make good PMs aren't out to maximize their income but instead have some income threshold above which the non-monetary benefits of the work (which is uniquely excellent!) dominate their mental calculus. Without being tied to any government pay scales, we can negotiate this threshold with individuals.

It's possible to systematize the whole program-creating process

Validating this hypothesis looks like getting to a place where after we've created some hopefully-not-too-large number of programs, we (internally, at least) feel confidence that it wasn't just a fluke. Ideally, we would also be able to instill that confidence into people outside the organization as well. The ability to repeatedly create good programs is a strong reason to believe that it might be successful in the long run.

A good chunk of systemizing program creation will entail nothing but explicitly paying attention to what works and what doesn't while going after the previous hypotheses. However, I also suspect that more abstract work on program design as a discipline will also be important. Perhaps you could look at them as the empirical and theoretical sides of the same coin.

It's possible to execute on programs in a way that relaxes academic/startup constraints

Program designs are useless if they don't translate into useful outcomes. People won't just see a roadmap and leap into action β€” there will almost by definition be significant friction, since we're explicitly going after programs that we suspect wouldn't happen otherwise in the current system. As a result, getting programs done will be a challenge!

It's easy to imagine scenarios where we run workshops, create precise ideas about the riskiest questions in them, know the exact right people to work on different parts of the program, and even do some seedling experiments to show that what we're proposing is not impossible, and yet fall flat on our faces when it comes to a full program. Coordinating multiple long-term research projects and synthesizing them into a working technology is an entirely different beast.

A clear failure mode is that we fail to achieve escape velocity from existing incentive structures. Maybe all the people who have the experience to do the work still want to optimize for publishing papers. Maybe the program requires coordination between a number of disparate groups, and all of those groups want to optimize their particular piece instead of accepting constraints that make the entire program eventually successful. Maybe there are legal problems with the researcher's organizations. Maybe the people working on the program graduate or get a job offer halfway through. The list goes on.

The overarching hypothesis is that we'll be able to avoid these known pitfalls, discover and avoid the unknown unknowns and successfully execute on full programs. De-risking program execution entails several sub-hypotheses:

It will be possible to coordinate several research projects toward a coherent goal

Coordination is hard. Research is hard. Coordinating research is going to be extra hard. Dealing with dependencies between projects will be a challenge both on the technical front and the human front. Technical coordination will require figuring out how to keep each project going despite hiccups in other projects. Human coordination will require making sure people communicate and get along. These are normal management problems, but they will be turned up to 11. The distributed nature of early programs will compound with the fact that doing anything new (especially with atoms) makes it harder to have shared context. At the same time, shared context will be critical!

To illustrate what the coordination problems might look like, let's look at an imaginary program to use molecular machines in metal-organic frameworks to do one-shot molecular synthesis. There might be one project to create better simulations for a molecular process, one project to design a series of molecular machines that could potentially turn a multi-step synthesis process into a single-shot process, and one project to synthesize the system. Friction can pop up all over the place: Benchmarks for the simulation need to be processes that are actually relevant for the second group; the design group and the implementation group need to avoid both designing something that is actually impossible to create and also limiting themselves to conservative designs that would be straightforward to create.

There are many ways to potentially address these coordination problems, all of which need experimental de-fuzzification. PMs can check in regularly with each group, not to crack the whip about progress but to check on what each group needs from the others and whether they're getting it. One of the PM's roles will be keeping the bigger program goal front and center and figuring out when an individual group needs to do something "suboptimal" in order to maximize the entire system. Another tactic is to regularly bring together the people actually doing the work on each project (as opposed to just the PIs) before they have results, so that people across the program can build rapport talking about real research problems instead of defending results.

The early pieces of work will be done by some combination of academic labs, contract R&D orgs, independent researchers, and possibly people within corporate R&D who are able to do work for grants

This hypothesis has three implicit sub-hypotheses: 1. The early work in programs will be done in distributed external organizations; 2. the types of groups that will do that work will be heterogeneous β€” that is, it won't just be academic labs; 3. PMs should be agnostic to the types of organizations doing the work as long as they can get it done.

Any one of these sub-hypotheses could be wrong! Other private organizations, like Ink & Switch and various open-source projects have pulled off distributed, externalized, research but that may not translate to atom-based solutions R&D. It may turn out that externalized non-computer-science research only works when you're a government organization with massive resources that can buy work at contract research organizations like SRI or APL. Academic labs might have draconian licensing or university overhead requirements that rule them out as potential partners. Independent researchers, regardless of their ability, might not have access to the equipment they would need to undertake a project.

However, I'm optimistic that there will be ways around these potential problems!

People will be willing to shift their organizational affiliations to an exploratory program organization as the program goes on

This hypothesis exists at two levels: Would people from different projects in a program be willing to shift into a single organization? And is consolidating into a single organization even a good idea? I lay out the reasoning for why exploratory program organizations might be a good idea in Part II, so I won't dig into it here. To the question of whether people would be willing to join the EPO, like most human systems, there are many factors at play, and it's impossible to predict all of them a priori. How much people come to care about the program they're working on would ideally be a deciding factor, but in reality, it's a complicated mix of incentives: what career track they see themselves on; what the opportunity cost of joining is; how they weight the chance of a good outcome; etc. Managing all of these incentives will be a major challenge.

It's possible to "graduate" programs in a way that gives them a life of their own

"Manage the transfer, not the technology: Innovative leaders with some successes tend to appoint themselves loonshot judge and jury (the Moses Trap). Instead, create a natural process for projects to transfer from the loonshot nursery to the field, and for valuable feedback and market intelligence to cycle back from the field to the nursery. Help manage the timing of the transfer: not too early (fragile loonshots will be permanently crushed), not too late (making adjustments will be difficult). Intervene only as needed, with a gentle hand. In other words, be a gardener, not a Moses."

β€”Safi Bahcall, Loonshots

Even if PARPA manages to nurture programs all the way from baby seedlings to impressive results, all that work will be worthless if the programs don't have a positive impact on the world. In order for that impact to happen, the programs need to take on lives of their own. There are many ways that technology can take on a life of its own, but unfortunately, none of them are as easy as just kissing it and hoping the gods do the rest. It could end up as an "open" project, be carried forward by a nonprofit, absorbed into an existing organization, or become the core of a startup. Regardless of the outcome, I suspect that explicitly thinking about which outcomes to target and course-correcting toward them will maximize the viability of programs after being part of PARPA.

Bringing technology to life is harder and hopefully less awkward than this.

One sub-hypothesis of "graduating" programs is that there is a lot of pre-work that can be done during the course of a program to maximize its impact after it concludes. It would be easy to focus monomaniacally on getting to some tremendous milestone, reach it, and then look around and ask "OK, what do we do with this now?" Or worse, assert, "Well, our job here is done, it's up to others to carry the torch forward!" Instead, PMs could act a bit like curling sweepers β€” altering the friction in front of the program ever so slightly so it ends up in the best place possible.

This "pre-work" will involve going back and forth with potential manufacturers ("What would make this technology actually producible at scale?"), potential adopters ("What specs do you actually care about? Why don't you use something like this already?"), and regulators so that the previous two groups aren't worried. The PM/program team will obviously need to make a call on what to incorporate into their work β€” throw out "I want a faster horse!" But keep "Power/weight ratio doesn't matter to us, but power/volume does." There will also be hard questions around what "form factor" would maximize diffusion β€” Is it a product? A process upgrade? A lab that does a particular kind of microscopy or synthesis work? Does it perhaps need to be the starting point for another program? A lot of this work closely resembles standard startup best practices β€” I imagine them both as "finding a fit in the real world," but where a startup is trying to optimize long-term capturable value through a scalable product, a PARPA program has more degrees of freedom.

Focusing too intently on what will happen after the program ends could have deleterious warping effects as well! As we've beaten to death already, one of the reasons PARPA needs to exist in the first place is because existing institutions focus work on outcomes like papers or profit. Navigating between the drive to enable potentially impactful work and nudging that work so that it actually delivers on that impact is yet another unavoidable tension that PARPA must confront.

Another sub-hypothesis is that in order to successfully "graduate," a program needs some of the people who were working on it to carry it forward. Intellectual continuity matters. And of course, we suspect that some of the program participants will want to graduate with the program. This intellectual continuity could take many forms β€” consulting with other organizations implementing the technology, starting a startup or nonprofit, perhaps something less conventional. The key thing is that at least one person who worked on the technology full-time continues to do so. It's a common misconception that "technology transfer" can happen by handing off some patents and perhaps some light part-time consulting work. This might have been the case in the past, when patents were schematics of a mechanical part, but no longer! As a result, it will be important for at least a few of the people in a (temporary) PARPA program to see it as a long-term endeavor.

PARPA will eventually spin out companies

Spinning out 253 as a company is only one of several ways that programs can "graduate." However, it's worth talking about them directly, because startups dominate so much of the cultural zeitgeist and potentially play a unique role in PARPA's business plans.

At the end of the day, PARPA's goal is roughly to unlock more technologically enabled wonder in the world. The "in the world" part does a lot of work. It demands technological diffusion, which can happen in one of three (not mutually exclusive) ways: You can sell technology directly, you can give it away, or you can build an organization around it.

Some of PARPA's work will certainly be appropriate for selling directly to companies that might diffuse it. However, there will be many things that just don't fit into the existing product lines or business models of current organizations.

Giving away non-software technologies tends to have limited diffusive potential outside of an institutional framework. Most people don't make their own stuff, so if you just put designs on the internet, they're unlikely to be widely used. There are of course counterexamples, but more often the diffusion of free or open technology is eventually driven by organizations. Penicillin needed Pfizer; the semiconductor needed Fairchild; electricity needed Edison Electric.

The importance of companies for diffusing technology means that PARPA will (sometimes) need to spin out companies in order for it to achieve its goals.

There are, of course, caveats: Not all of these companies will be high-growth startups. Even though a technology might be at a point where it needs a company to carry it forward, that doesn't necessarily mean that company will be a good venture capital investment. The appropriate structure for some of these companies might even be as nonprofits, like the Mozilla or Wikimedia foundations.

It's possible for this entire cycle to eventually become autocatalytic

The longest-term, vaguest, and most aggressive hypothesis is that it's possible for this entire cycle of program design, execution, and graduation to become "autocatalytic" β€” that is, PARPA can (and must) become its own money factory. Autocatalyzation isn't just about money, but something bigger: a cycle where good results beget good results.

Why does autocatalyzation matter? The underlying meta-hypothesis is that PARPA will only be able to achieve truly miraculous things if it plays a long game. Good research has long time scales β€” it took the industrial labs of the 20th century decades to hit their stride. It's fairly unsubstantiated, but it feels like an organization's time scales need to be even longer than the work it undertakes. There are also compounding returns to institutional competence in high-variance domains. Of course, this meta-hypothesis could be wrong as well! There are several research organizations that were flashes in the pan but produced outsized results: The Rad Lab and Willow Garage leap to mind.

I suspect that in order to thrive in the long run, PARPA needs to be as in control of its own fate as possible. If PARPA never stops depending on external capital, it will eventually fall into one incentive trap or another. Even with the best funders, the wisest leaders, and the most robust organizational structures, if you roll a die enough times you'll eventually roll a natural 1. Of course, autocatalyzation does not guarantee success, but it seems like an eventually-important part of it.

We can divide the hypothesis that PARPA's "core gameplay loop" can become autocatalyzing into three sequential sub-hypotheses:

1. PARPA can create a community that generates good inbounds and enables more successful programs. The first hint that PARPA can become self-sustaining may not be monetary at all. In the early days, we will need to spend significant effort hunting down good performers and programs. If PARPA is doing good, differentiated work, this should shift over time and we should be able to become a honeypot for excellent people who want work to with us and ideas that couldn't live anywhere else. You can tell a lot about both people and organizations by the company they keep. An autocatalyzing community is of course insufficient for an autocatalyzing organization. However, it may be necessary and will happen more quickly than monetary autocatalyzation, thereby providing an early "test" of the autocatalyzation hypothesis.

2. PARPA can get to a "pseudo-autocatalytic" state where the organization is getting enough consistent free cash flow through some combination of donations, spin-offs, and other sources that it feels "default alive." For a long while, PARPA will be living pretty hand to mouth β€” we'll be able to raise money here and there but they will be one-off events. At some point after demonstrating promising results (and probably after creating an autocatalyzing community), funding will become dependable and/or large enough to create a small buffer. People will donate regularly, or larger amounts; spin-offs might have a few successful exits, encouraging more people to invest; we could establish a consortium or consulting agreements that bring in revenue. At this point we will have flipped from "default dead" to "default alive." See " Default Alive or Default Dead ." This state will still be full of incentive traps and therefore long-term unstable but will nevertheless be a significant step.

3. Full autocatalyzation can only happen by building up an endowment, which will be possible by squirreling away excess from the pseudo-autocatalytic process. An endowment that funds operations out of the interest on a large principal seems like the ideal funding mechanism for a DARPA-riff β€” the question is whether building one is a chimera. Our working hypothesis is that building an endowment will be extremely hard and likely to fail but isn't impossible. It will take a long time and strong financial discipline; as I noted in the section on endowments, it's a bad idea to try to build it all at once, so it will need to be built up slowly over time by limiting expenses to a portion of the organization's revenue. A big assumption here is that funders and investors will be on board with this plan!

PARPA can and should create a replicable institutional model

There are several attributes of solutions R&D and PARPA that suggest that in order to maximize awesome in the world, we should explicitly think about how to create a replicable institutional model while building PARPA. The model is inherently unscalable and institutional models are generally more robust than any individual institution. This final hypothesis is more of a meta-hypothesis that we should be paying attention to throughout every stage of the organization.

While PARPA will hopefully be able to accomplish many important things, it will be structurally unable to do all the important things. Companies can conceivably 255 monopolize an entire market and provide all the search, steel, cat videos, or diapers in the world. By contrast, DARPA's tiny and flat structure likely plays a key role in their success See the section " DARPA is relatively tiny and flat " in "Why Does DARPA Work?" and any organization riffing on its model will see diminishing returns beyond its size. 257 This may be similar to what you see in venture capital firms and many private equity firms β€” small firms are able to get crazy returns on outlier results while large ones revert to the mean.

Blazing the trail for new institutional structures is far more impactful than any given institution. The impressive thing about Sequoia and Don Draper is less the investments they made but the fact that they created a template for an entire institutional model.

Contingent factors can always kill a given organization even if it gets the model correct. Or perhaps like ARDC, For much more about ARDC, see Creative Capital: Georges Doriot and the Birth of Venture Capital . arguably the first VC firm, you get the idea and some pieces correct but screw up others (like legal structures) in an ultimately fatal way.

What would you do differently if you're trying to create a replicable model vs. just building a one-off? One piece is to consciously document decisions and failures β€” why you do one thing over another and things you tried that didn't work. Additionally, it means forgoing a level of secrecy and being open to helping people who want to do something similar.

PARPA's ideal legal structure comprises both a Nonprofit and a for-profit

Note: Many of the decisions in this section are based on numerical assumptions. I've marked each of these assumptions with a πŸ“Š. I've put these quantitative factors into a model that can be referenced here, so you can copy it and play with it yourself.

Another note: This is a description of a hypothetical platonic ideal β€” there are surely things in this section that are either illegal or pragmatically impractical because key people will say, "Ha, no, I'm not signing that." However, it's important to start from somewhere precise!

The ideal legal structure for PARPA would satisfy three conditions:

  1. The legal structure should enable people to make tax-deductible donations to the organization but also be able to channel for-profit investments toward valuable work.
  2. The legal structure should enable the organization and the people involved in it to participate in some upside of capturing value from technologies they've created.
  3. The legal structure should enable the organization to become self-sustaining. A self-sustaining organization either needs to sell a product or service, have an endowment, or regularly generate liquidatable equity.

On its face, these three conditions seem contradictory. In aggregate, we can't expect an organization that seriously tackles solutions R&D to be profitable. Especially if it focuses on the work that the relatively efficient market in for-profit organizations won't touch.

However, while an aggregate of all of PARPA's activities will not be profitable, it's a reasonable (but still risky) hypothesis that a portfolio of companies spun out of PARPA could end up doing well. Regardless of profit, PARPA will eventually spin out companies because companies can be an effective mechanism for technology diffusion. It's an even safer bet that if PARPA is doing something useful, there will end up being many profit-generating organizations that can trace their DNA back to PARPA. But let's ignore the latter for now. 259

This will be a sketch of the simplest structure that (I believe) meets all three criteria β€” let's call it the platonic structure, because implementing it will undoubtedly involve some changes for pragmatic reasons, like "not going to prison on a technicality." In a sentence, you have a Big-N Nonprofit that owns a C-corp and also has an endowment. For convenience, let's name them after the muses Nete, Calliope, and Euterpe, because it will make the section much more interesting than saying "the Nonprofit," "the C-corp," and "the endowment" over and over again. Nete runs all of PARPA's activities. Her operating capital comes from three places: tax-exempt donations from donors, cash from Calliope, and dividends from Euterpe. Calliope owns parts of companies that spin out of Nete either as equity in the case of high-growth companies or as profit-share agreements in the case of low-growth companies. People can invest in Calliope in exchange for a claim on future profits. Finally, Euterpe does what endowments do: She invests money broadly and attempts to generate a steady dividend that she gives to Nete. Euterpe gets money either directly from donors or from Nete when her revenues exceed her expenses.

At a high level, this structure satisfies criteria #1 by enabling people who prefer to make tax-deductible donations to donate either directly to Nete's operational budget or to Euterpe. The structure satisfies criteria #2 by enabling people to invest in only the outcomes of programs that eventually become companies, which I do suspect could create real returns, as opposed to the structure as a whole. Finally, the structure satisfies criteria #3 through the fact that Nete is the "parent org" and a reasonable hypothesis about how Euterpe can get to a point where she can sustain operations. πŸ“Š

There are several nuances, especially around Calliope, the C-corp. The first nuance is about how Calliope's stake in spin-out companies works. We've already established thatPARPA will eventually spin out companies. However, it's important to reiterate both that not every successful program will turn into a companyπŸ“Š and that not every company will be a high-growth venture-backable startup. Sometimes the best vehicle to get a technology out into the world is a small, specialized organization. Standard equity ownership does not make sense for slow-growth companies because they may never be acquired or go public. Instead, Calliope could own a share of their future profits. This profit-sharing will end up being negligible on the for-profit's balance sheet in a best-case-scenarioπŸ“Š but it is a useful source of free cash flow. So, in order to maximize technology getting out into the world, it's important to offer companies a choice of profit- or equity-based ownership. The size of that ownership is another tricky matter.πŸ“Š The more ownership Calliope maintains in the baby companies, the less profit or equity they'll have to fund their own operations, and the less likely they are to succeed. At the same time, Calliope needs to own enough to make a return for her investors. As anchors, Y Combinator takes 7% and Entrepreneur First takes 10%. We'll go with 10% because it's a nice round number and any higher number feels like it could cause significant damage to a startup. Perhaps it should be lower.

The next nuance is about Calliope's legal status. The two main choices are whether she should be an LLC or a C-corp. The most pertinent differences between the two revolve around taxes and the ability to issue shares. LLCs are "pass-through" legal structures, so only investors would be taxed on income they make from Calliope. As a C-corp, both Calliope and her investors would be taxed. C-corps have much more legal precedence and people are more comfortable with them, so unless the double taxation is a significant burden, it's generally a good idea to default to a C-corp. The way to navigate this trade-off is to look at where Calliope's (hypothetical) value is going to come from and which structure would maximize technological diffusion. (Do not forget our goal!) The majority of Calliope's value will be in holding equity in companies that are high value. The classic trap here is to set up Calliope's incentives so that she is incentivized to lean on those companies to have a liquidity event as soon as possible. Calliope would be incentivized to push for liquidity events if her value were in the cash she would be returning to investors. Instead, it would be better if Calliope's value were based on the long-term value of the equity she held. Aligning those incentives seems to suggest that Calliope should be a C-corp. While this might be an obvious conclusion to you, it was not actually my first assumption. The one other consideration that might tip the balance is that there are more constraints on how ownership works in an LLC than a C-corp.

The next nuance is how ownership of Calliope will work. The ways that you can legally divide up ownership in an organization are heavily regulated, so I am going to first describe a platonic system that is probably illegal and then explain how it could be crudely implemented within the constraints of the law. Obviously, investors and Nete herself are going to own a good chunk of Calliope, but it's also important to figure out how to enable Nete's PMs to participate as well. Enabling PMs to own a meaningful part of Calliope is actually important to incentives, when you consider that there will be some programs that will naturally lead to valuable companies but other programs will be hugely impactful while not leading to good companies. If the implicit choice for PMs is "If your program becomes a company, you'll get financial upside but if it doesn't you get nothing," you will incentivize PMs to either push programs that shouldn't become companies toward becoming companies or to never start uncommercializable programs in the first place. If instead you give everybody some slice of the value Calliope captures, it will hopefully alleviate that pressure. Of course, this won't stop PMs who are strongly driven by economic incentives from skewing all their work toward companies. Nor will it create totally equal outcomes β€” PMs who go on to create successful companies will obviously own far more of those companies; arguably, the majority of a technology company's "excess value" is not actually due to its technology. See " Productive Uncertainty ," again.

Ownership based on an accumulating "ledger" of points would enable everybody involved in the organization β€” both those who put in money and those who put in time β€” to participate in upside on roughly equal ground. You could assign different numbers of points for different activities that help the the enterprise as a whole: "You get N points for the first year of service, 1.2*N for the next year, etc." "You get M points per $100K." At the end of the day, you end up with a list of people and how many points each of them has β€” ownership is just your points divided by the total number of points. The ledger system ultimately has the same outcome as selling and awarding people shares that get progressively diluted as a company increases in value. (More points will be created over time, so a fixed number of points will represent a decreasing fraction of Calliope.) However, a point system has several positive features that standard shares do not and avoids some of their downsides. One upside to this system is that it gives everybody the same type of ownership: avoiding preferred shares, etc. The ledger can roughly stand as an accounting of who contributed to the organization's success. 261 Combined with "pseudopoints" for donations to the nonprofit (which can't be financially rewarded), the ledger could be a public source of pride instead of a secret and source of jealousy like company ownership normally is.

The points system would also enable people to participate in multiple ways instead of different types of shares shunting people into different buckets according to their roles; there would be no accounting hassle for an employee who also wanted to invest. There's also a psychological component in the difference between adding a grain to a growing pile of sand and getting a slice of a fixed pie. I realize this all comes with a whiff of utopian faeries and rainbows β€” regulatory constraints and investor pressure will undoubtedly make this full system infeasible. It's important to lay it out, however, so that we can get as close as possible without going to jail.

The trickiest pieces of the puzzle are the questions of who does the work, who owns it, and who employs people. It would be awkward if Nete had a bunch of employees who just happened to get compensated with a stake in Calliope. A tentatively feasible way to separate Nete and Calliope is as follows: All of the PMs are Calliope's employees. They are then contracted to Nete, who owns any resulting work. If the work gets to the point where a company makes sense, Nete then can license that work at fair market value to Calliope, who would then spin out companies. At least in theory, this arrangement allows PMs to have an equity stake while at the same time making sure that Nete, not Calliope (and therefore profit), is driving research agendas.

Calliope's existence won't free Nete from depending on donations to fund operations for many years. However, Calliope can possibly free Nete from depending on donations in the long run by filling Euterpe's coffers. This scheme relies on two big assumptions β€” that Calliope will eventually become very valuable, and/or that Nete will be able to get enough donations to cover operations so that, through some combination of those donations and money from Calliope, there will be enough to slowly build up Euterpe's principal to the point where its dividends can fund Nete indefinitely.πŸ“Š

PARPA will go through three phases of organizational growth

Organizations tend to resemble punctuated equilibria Evolutionary systems (may) go through long periods of slow change punctuated by periods of rapid change. See " Punctuated equilibria: an alternative to phyletic gradualism ." β€” instead of always changing at a continuous rate, they tend to go through periods of relative stability punctuated by "phase shifts" when they hit a critical level of resources. In other words, organizations evolve more like PokΓ©mon than (growing) people.

Most organizations go through different forms but rarely make them explicit. Instead, the situation resembles the South Park Underpants Gnomes" business plan: There's an initial form (collect underpants) and a final form (profit) with a big question mark in between them. It's hard to evaluate how good such a plan is from the outside, but perhaps more importantly, it's hard to use a gnomish plan internally β€” when should you push to the next phase? When should you exert discipline and remain in the current phase because you haven't met key conditions for a phase shift? Making the different forms explicit can get everybody on the same page. As with so many other things, making forms legible also makes them vulnerable β€” both to criticism and to accusations of hypocrisy if they end up not playing out as predicted (which is almost inevitable). In my calculus, the clarity and intellectual honesty is worth the risk.

Through this lens, we can think about PARPA as taking on different "forms" over time. Each form will require different resources, focus on a different set of activities, and generate different outputs. These forms roughly correspond to each of the major hypotheses on PARPA's path through the idea maze.

PARPA could use tranches to walk the line between long-term funding and step-by-step de-risking

One pragmatic reason to explicitly divide PARPA's development into discrete forms is to enable tranches for both donors and investors. As I've noted several times, there are many tensions between starting small and the other pieces of the DARPA ,odel. Tranched donations and funding could be one way to relax this tension. For some more complex and well thought-out tranched funding schemes, see " Funding Long Shots ."

Milestone-based funding is common in the pharmaceutical world, where developing a drug takes many years and potentially billions of dollars yet follows a fairly predictable trajectory through the different stages of FDA approval. The predictability and structure do not reduce the risk associated with the venture, but they do reduce the uncertainty about possible outcomes.

PARPA could conceivably raise money in a similar way β€” soliciting small donations that are automatically followed up by larger ones once specific milestones are hit. This approach would allow the organization to act as though it had secured long-term funding without being under the pressure to deploy a large amount of money. Milestone-based funding would also allow donors and funders to hold onto their money until the milestones were hit and feel like the organization was de-risked before deploying larger amounts of money.

One danger is that a donor could choose to renege on their commitment once a milestone is hit. This unfortunately happens with capital calls in funds, but hopefully, the chances of it happening in this case could be small, both because hitting milestones will be less unexpected than a capital call (which could come at any time) and clear milestones could enable a firmer contract.

Creating and agreeing on milestones will be a challenge. Milestone-based tranches require clear milestones. One of the reasons they work so well in medical technology and drugs is that passing FDA trials are unambiguous milestones that everybody can agree on. PARPA won't have the luxury(?) of a staged government gatekeeper as the primary barrier to success, so we'll need to select milestones carefully and do the work to get donors to buy into them. My intention is that laying out the forms below is a first step in that process!

Form 1: Program Design οΏΌοΏΌ

  • People: 1–5
  • Budget: $0–500K/year
  • Outputs: Program designs

In this form, PARPA will be just one or two full-time individuals designing possible programs. Remember, it is important for big things to start small ! These PMs will be focused on an iterated process of hub-and-spoke-style work, where a PM reads many papers and talks to many people to form their own hypotheses and couples that with many-to-many workshops where several experts come together to hash out possibilities.

In this form, the organization's primary output will be artifacts β€” let's call them roadmaps. These living documents will work backward from a clear goal to the precise work that would maximize your chance of getting to that goal; call out who might be best suited to do that work (there are many pieces of equipment or tacit knowledge that only exist in one or two places in the world!); and explain how to think about the work in terms of timelines, branch points, and milestones. The roadmaps will inevitably need a few iterations of real experiments to de-risk key assumptions . Keep in mind that a roadmap doesn't mean that a program is "shovel-ready." There will be a lot of work to get all the pieces in place like figuring out who will do the work, signing contracts, sorting out equipment, etc. Ideally, other organizations would act on these roadmaps, but I wouldn't bet on it.

Ideally, we will evolve out of this form as quickly as possible once we have a good handle on the hypothesis that it's possible to design programs in a systematic (and therefore repeatable) way .

There is no critical mass to get to this stage, but the critical mass to get out of it is to have designed around five programs that are worth moving forward with. 264 We need to generate a sufficient number of roadmaps to show both that the planning process is repeatable and that there are enough areas in PARPA's early sweet spot to make this whole endeavor worthwhile.

The budget for this stage is just enough to cover individual salaries and the costs of running workshops β€” renting out a cabin in the woods and (hopefully) food and transportation for people, so a few thousand dollars. The tricky bit here is that our ability to dig into problems and possibilities deeply enough to do good program design may be coupled to our ability to execute on those programs. In my experience, 265 people are much more willing to talk shop about precise potentials when they can see the conversation leading to an actual program.

If other organizations do want to act on the roadmaps, there is perhaps a Form 1.5, in which the boundaries between PARPA and the executing organizations become fuzzier. We could bring representatives from those organizations into the process to increase the chance that the output becomes reality. Similarly, PARPA people could consult with organizations executing on roadmaps to keep the roadmaps alive and make sure nothing is lost in translation.

Form 2: Architecting Institute

  • People: 5–20
  • Budget: $10M/year
  • Outputs: Self-sufficient but temporary research organizations

In this form PARPA will comprise several program managers working on program design but expand beyond Form 1's process by running seedling experiments and getting programs off the ground. The organization's primary output will be (semi) independent organizations along the lines of focused research organizations See "Focused Research Organizations to Accelerate Science, Technology, and Medicine ," again. whose mission is to execute on a program.

Once a PM has driven a program to a point where they have good answers to all the questions in the the Heilmeier Catechism See https://www.darpa.mil/work-with-us/heilmeier-catechism . or an equivalent "gate', 268 they would need to get all the pieces in place for the full program organization β€” funding, incorporation, research contracts, and hiring β€” and either move to the program organization full-time or transition leadership to someone else.

The funding for these program-executing organizations could come from a myriad of sources β€” the government, philanthropists, or investors, depending on the nature of the work to be done. Frankly, this transition from a loose set of connected projects to its own organization seems incredibly tricky to do well. There are many disconnected pieces that need to come together. Compromises to get funding or convince people to join could end up derailing the program. PARPA should be able to help the creation of these temporary organizations by maintaining connections to funding sources, labs, and contract research organizations, providing initial space, and generally honing process knowledge. It might be possible to get around these problems by building out the idea of exploratory program organizations that enable a program to undergo a more continuous transition to an independent entity.

There is a minimum number of programs that PARPA needs to be working on in parallel β€” probably in the five to seven range. If the programs are actually high risk, any single one is more likely to fail than not, so if there were only a few programs, the chances that all of them would go nowhere and take down the whole organization with them would be quite high. If each program has a 5–10% chance of success (as is the case in DARPA See " DARPA - Enabling Technical Innovation ." ), then you need to run seven programs to get a 50% chance of seeing one of them succeed .

A critical mass of programs needs a critical mass of program managers to run them. In addition to the bare minimum number of people needed to run the programs, there's some number above which the group starts passively generating more ideas than all the individuals on their own. This number is probably around five to seven: a dinner party's worth of people. 270

This form is where the director emerges as a separate role to focus on the organization itself. The director wasn't even worth mentioning in Form 1 because in the beginning the director will be basically be a PM with some extra administrative work.

Estimating the minimum level for the budget in Form 2 is tricky. Too low and you're unable to do the work to show that the whole organization has potential. DARPA seedling programs have total budgets between $1–5M. If we assume that you want to complete the program in 6–18 months, that's a rate of $0.7–10M per program per year. If you need a critical mass of five programs at any one time, that's $3.5–50M per year in research costs. Obviously, this is a huge range, drawn from multiplying the extreme ends of the time/budget spectrum. A more reasonable estimate would probably be $10M/year. This number feels like it's skirting the edge of setting the organization up to fail because of the inevitable pressure to deliver results ASAP. So in total, the critical budget to consider moving to this stage is around ~$10M/year, but hopefully higher.

While the $10M/year number is tiny compared to the amount that the US government spends on research, it is massive compared to most relatively new organizations. Donors might be understandably hesitant to commit to that amount for the several years you would need to see real outputs. Ideally, verdicts would be withheld until after the created semi-independent programs had a chance to show results. This is a place where tranches could be clutch.

Form 3: An Institute for Creative Technology

  • People: 20–100
  • Budget: $60M–3B/year
  • Outputs: Open research, companies

This phase is the fully evolved version of PARPA that can hopefully exist productively for a very long time. In this phase, PARPA will not only design and de-risk programs but will run them as well.

Running programs without creating and funding an entire new organization has several advantages. Internal programs enable higher-risk programs because you can shift money away from a failed program to a healthy one. Internal programs smooth the transition from "Hey, we should do this!" to actually doing it β€” you don't have to go and raise a bunch of money, transfer knowledge, and spin up a whole organization. Instead, all of that can happen organically over the course of the program.

In this phase, the organization's outputs are whatever the programs turn into β€” whether it's startup companies, research nonprofits, or knowledge and IP that we work to diffuse into existing organizations. PARPA will still need to do a lot of work to make sure that the programs transition to whatever form will maximize their impact. Everything else about the organization will be a fairly natural extension from Form 2.

Like Form 2, Form 3 does need a critical mass of simultaneous programs because of the program's high chances of failure. This number is probably around seven, based on the back-of-the-envelope exercise that a 10% success rate requires seven programs in order to give the organization a 50% chance of a single successful program. Assuming each of seven programs costs ~$8M/year and you're continuing to do seedling programs as well (per Form 2), you wind up with a minimum budget of ~$60M/year. Interestingly, this number roughly corresponds to the original ARPA IPTO budget that midwifed the personal computer ($2020 47M).

Eventually, we aim to get to the scale of DARPA: ~100 programs with program managers deploying a budget of ~$3B. Of course, that steady state can and should be approached incrementally after many years of operation. I realize this target is incredibly ambitious and there is a large chance we will never get there!

Potential programs

I struggle with how far down the ladder of abstraction to climb when talking about specific programs. On the one hand, I have built a few strong hypotheses, and having examples is always helpful for what is otherwise a very abstract proposal. On the other hand, readers (not you, of course, but other people) tend to over-focus on those examples to the point where questions and disagreements over the examples dominate everything else. ("Forget all the models, forget the plans, why are you working on that ?") Which programs we'll work on is both one of the most important and least fixed pieces of the plan. But I've already asserted that precise visions are more likely to happen, so I will hold myself to my word. Keep in mind that these are hunches that need a lot of work to even verify that they're worth creating a program around. As it says on open house furniture: for display only (but perhaps available later). In this section, I'll present both a list of hypotheses that may be worth designing programs around and two more detailed descriptions of programs I suspect are particularly promising.

Some program hypotheses

A caveat: You are probably going to think that most of these examples are objectionable for one reason or another. Some will sound like fantastic ramblings, others will sound too eminently practicable to need new institutional support.

  • Reconfigurable black-box factories are a systems and robotics problem that could drastically change what gets made where.
  • 3D printing could potentially enable soft robotics to become a useful thing.
  • Non-human-centric biology could unlock new paradigms of physical technology. For example, you could make high strength to weight linear actuators that effectively run on garbage if you could create an artificial muscle coupled to an artificial metabolism.
  • Multi-purpose farming robotics could change the way we grow food, especially indoors.
  • New simulation paradigms β€” especially hierarchical systems of simulations β€” could enable everything from new materials to generative design and new generations of robotics.
  • 'General purpose" telerobotics is a systems engineer problem that could both address global problems and enable people to do things they never could before.
  • "Positional chemistry" driven by some combination of protein 3D printers, nanomachines embedded in metal-organic frameworks, and other tools could begin to deliver on the vision of atomically precise manufacturing.

General purpose telerobotics

Possibilities

One of the most iconic scenes in The Matrix occurs soon after Neo has escaped the Matrix for the first time and is learning that he can download in-Matrix skills directly into his brain. He plugs a cable into the back of his neck, thrashes around, opens his eyes, and announces, "I know kung fu." It has become shorthand for the idea of "downloading" an ability. While telerobotic technology cannot give people superpowers directly, it can create many of the outcomes. There is something intangibly beautiful about giving people more agency. In the same way that computers can be a "bicycle for the mind," enhancing our creativity and thinking abilities, robots could be a "computer for the hands.'

The first and most obvious power that telerobotics can give people is the ability to teleport. There are obvious benefits (less commuting for physical jobs, an expert chef being able to cook for people around the world, etc.), but one of the less obvious ones is the ability to fully utilize relatively rare pieces of equipment. At 2 a.m., people on the other side of the world can continue research work.

Teleoperated robots could be the size of buildings. In addition to fulfilling everyone's fantasies of commanding giant mechs, massive remotely operated robots could do the work of large crews on construction sites or during emergencies. Both are high-uncertainty situations where we won't be trusting fully automated robots anytime soon. On the flip side, teleoperated robots could be small enough to go inside a human body, crawl inside walls, and generally operate in places a person could never access non-destructively. Robots the size of pills could make The Fantastic Journey a (less adventurous) reality. To some extent, this already exists in the tools for laprasocopic surgery and the da Vinci robot. However, we should see these as crude hints of what is possible. Robots can have a plethora of form factors. Researchers have worked on everything from snake robots to gecko robots and octopus robots. Telerobotic technology can enable people to utilize the advantages of these form factors like any shape-shifting superhero.

Even at human scale, robots can have physical abilities far beyond those of humans. Electricity-powered robots don't need air. Robotic hands can hold things that are much hotter or colder than a human can. Powerful motors can enable a robot (and, by extension its operator) to have superhuman strength, while precise stepper motors can enable people to act with steady precision that few human hands can. Regardless of their main powers, superheroes are generally much more damage-resistant than normal people. A remotely operated robot enables squishy humans to approximate this damage resistance. There's also the fact that it's much more ethical to put a robot in danger than a person. For now, robots are so expensive and telerobotic technology is clunky enough that it's worthwhile to pay the liability insurance and send people into danger. Dedicated work on telerobotic technologies can change this "fact."

Challenges

If telerobotics is so great and not just a pipe dream, why are real telerobotics platforms basically just iPads on Segways? A big part of the answer is that there are many different pieces that need work in the context of a system. A general-purpose telerobot needs to enable a person to smoothly interact with an environment.

Without laying down telerobotics-dedicated cable, telerobots will always need to operate over the internet. That means dropped packets and variable lag. While these are slightly annoying during video calls, they can be disastrous for a delicate task. NaΓ―vely implemented, haptic feedback over a laggy connection can create a self-reinforcing loop that could (without force limiters) rip off an arm. There are many potential ways to get around lag: onboard autonomy that can translate "Rotate this" and "Pick that up" into lower-level path planning; generating a model of the robot's environment that a controller interacts with and then the system translates into robot movement on the other end; or the less technical approach of cutting a deal with a telecom company. The trick is that how well each of these approaches "works" depends on other pieces of the system.

Human touch is pretty extraordinary β€” pick up a pen if one's handy (any small object will do), read the next sentence, and then close your eyes. Once your eyes are closed, twiddle the pen in a few loops, bring it back to its original position, and then open your eyes again. The extraordinary thing is how easy that probably was. Most modern robots and telerobots operate primarily through visual sensors β€” either passive, like a CCD, or active, like LIDAR. Compared to gigapixel visual sensors, modern tactile sensors are primitive. Human skin can have neurite densities in the thousands per square millimeter, See " The density of remaining nerve endings in human skin with and without postherpetic neuralgia after shingles 00481-4)." while the cutting-edge BioTac tactile sensor measures forces via the differences between 19 electrodes. See "The BioTac - Multimodal Tactile Sensor." The situation isn't much better interfacing with the human hand on the other end. One upshot might be that the binding constraint on telerobotics is haptics technology. Perhaps! But at a system level, there may be ways to achieve better performance even with low-quality tactile sensors: multiple cameras, simulated tactile responses, Project Soli –style radar-on-a-chip, or autonomy in the loop.

Human hands are also versatile β€” those same hands that can thread a needle or hold a baby can also lift hundreds of pounds or smash a brick. Robotic actuators (the fancy word for "things that do physical things to the world") are nowhere near that good β€” either they're too weak to do any damage or liable to destroy things without very careful control. There are so many potential ways to improve this situation: from haptic feedback loops to mechanically compliant arms and soft grippers. Artificial muscles, pneumatic systems, and pulley-driven arms and hands are all potential ways to approach the versatility of human limbs and hands. The trick is (and I will sound like a broken record here) that the "best" solution only exists in the context of a system β€” if you have lower lag, you need to worry less about arm compliance; if you have a four-armed robot, you could switch between strong arms and delicate ones; etc.

So far, we've only talked about the technical challenges. There are many people-based constraints on telerobotic development. Telerobotics has become seen as the redheaded step child next to work on full autonomy. It's seen as nothing but a stepping stone to a near-future inevitability. Hopefully, previous sections at least nudged your belief that such assertions are like saying that work on productivity software is useless because it will all be automated anyway. The work that is happening is rarely done in a real context of use outside of a few exceptions; researchers usually demonstrate different subsystems on benchmark tasks, publish a paper, and call it a day. These benchmarks are barely even comparable because every telerobotics lab cobbles together its own unique setup from different commercially available components.

Actions

What would a PARPA program to go after general-purpose telerobotics look like?

One concrete possibility is to work with academic and commercial groups to create a standardized telerobotic research platform. Both the PR2 and Baxter ) robots simultaneously spurred a lot of robotics work by providing an extensible research platform and were commercial failures. PARPA, in its role of taking on work that both academia and startups won't touch, could coordinate work to build an extensible telerobot and the work to figure out how to make it a maximally useful general tool.

Another possibility might look like picking one extremely hard but obviously important context-of-use and then coordinating work to build a prototype system within that context. Hopefully, a challenging context of use with many contradictory requirements would prevent the system from overspecializing. The goal would be twofold: First we would try to get the system to a point where commercial entities see enough potential to move the ball forward. Second, you could imagine reaching a place where improvement is a matter of optimizing individual components, rather than the system as a whole. Elder care is the most salient context of use; it's important and involves everything from big, strenuous (but delicate) tasks, like physically helping someone move, to small precise things, like preparing food.

Positional chemistry

Possibilities

I'll stand on the shoulders of some giants:

Up to now, we have been content to dig in the ground to find minerals. We heat them and we do things on a large scale with them, and we hope to get a pure substance with just so much impurity, and so on. But we must always accept some atomic arrangement that nature gives us. We haven't got anything, say, with a "checkerboard" arrangement, with the impurity atoms exactly arranged 1,000 angstroms apart, or in some other particular pattern.

What could we do with layered structures with just the right layers? What would the properties of materials be if we could really arrange the atoms the way we want them? They would be very interesting to investigate theoretically. I can't see exactly what would happen, but I can hardly doubt that when we have some control of the arrangement of things on a small scale we will get an enormously greater range of possible properties that substances can have, and of different things that we can do.

Consider, for example, a piece of material in which we make little coils and condensers (or their solid state analogs) 1,000 or 10,000 angstroms in a circuit, one right next to the other, over a large area, with little antennas sticking out at the other end – a whole series of circuits. Is it possible, for example, to emit light from a whole set of antennas, like we emit radio waves from an organized set of antennas to beam the radio programs to Europe? The same thing would be to beam the light out in a definite direction with very high intensity. (Perhaps such a beam is not very useful technically or economically.)

...

But it is interesting that it would be, in principle, possible (I think) for a physicist to synthesize any chemical substance that the chemist writes down. Give the orders and the physicist synthesizes it. How? Put the atoms down where the chemist says, and so you make the substance. The problems of chemistry and biology can be greatly helped if our ability to see what we are doing, and to do things on an atomic level, is ultimately developed – a development which I think cannot be avoided.

β€”Richard Feynman, " There's Plenty of Room at the Bottom "

A short summary of what molecular nanotechnology will mean is thorough and inexpensive control of the structure of matter. Pollution, physical disease, and material poverty all stem from poor control of the structure of matter. Strip mines, clear-cutting, refineries, paper mills, and oil wells are some of the crude, twentieth-century technologies that will be replaced. Dental drills and toxic chemotherapies are others.

β€”K. Eric Drexler, Unbounding the Future

In short, successful positional chemistry would allow us to turn the arrangement of atoms from an indirect, stochastic process to a direct, designed process. Biology already does this β€” you could think of the relationship between positional chemistry and biological processes, like the action of ribosomes or kinesin, as similar to the relationship between aircraft and birds. Unfortunately we're still lashing wings to our arms and jumping off churches.

Challenges

You would need an entire book to do justice to the challenges facing anyone who wants to make the Feynman/Drexler vision a reality. However, it boils down to the fact that atoms aren't just little balls you can stick to one another. The atomic-scale world effectively has a different set of rules and demands almost entirely new engineering paradigms.

The world on the scale of atoms works very differently than our macro-world. (As an intuition pump, a carbon atom is ~0.3nm across, a water molecule is ~0.27nm, and DNA is ~2nm wide.) Gravity doesn't matter, everything is floppy and constantly jiggling, and quantum effects are a going concern. Some people argue See the Drexler-Smalley debate for strong arguments against positional chemistry. that these attributes make it impossible to do anything at this scale besides "stochastic building" β€” effectively putting a bunch of ingredients together, shaking, and counting on their properties to direct the process and output. While I'm optimistic that the properties of the nanoscale world don't make positional chemistry impossible, it will require drastically new ways of doing engineering.

I'll use the example of a DNA "3D printer" to illustrate some more general challenges in positional chemistry. 274 Imagine a DNA-based protein 3D printer/pick-and-place-machine β€” a precisely positioned write head that can pick up and exactly place prefabricated proteins on a work surface. At some point, any positional chemistry system needs to interface between stochastic processes and more deterministic ones at the same scale. The printer might need to change "tools" (antibody-like proteins?) by flowing a high-concentration solution of the new tools over the device. These tools will be constrained (for a long time) by the necessity to be fabricate them through traditional methods β€” putting stuff in a tube and shaking. The same goes for the protein "Lego bricks" that the printer is arranging. The bricks will need to fold the good old-fashioned way, so they'll be limited by the shapes and capabilities of amino acids (which, luckily, are provably capable of creating everything from bone to wood and shell). The upshot is that this will in no way be a "universal matter printer."

These constraints will cascade up to what you can build and the steps that you need to take to build it in ways that traditional engineering has no good way of wrapping its collective mind around. To make things even harder, the traditional engineering tools of models and simulations basically need to be reinvented for this new world. While the topics themselves still matter just as much (or more!), you would need to throw out your college textbooks on thermodynamics, statics, and dynamics. Great progress has been made on simulating processes on the nanoscale, but there is a lot of work to be done both on making the simulations more versatile and on using them as engineering tools.

And how do you know that your simulations were accurate? Observability is a challenge both for model development and for positional chemistry in general. Unlike a macro-scale system, you usually can't just look at a nanoscale system and see whether it looks like you expect it to based on the model. While scanning electron microscopes, atomic force microscopes, X-ray crystallography, and other tools make the nanoscale world not entirely inaccessible, they're severely limited in the conditions they can observe, and the data they produce often requires interpretation. In many situations, you're limited to observing secondary effects to tell you whether things are working the way you expect. These indirect observations make it harder to do failure analysis and increase the length of feedback loops, which is yet another challenge.

You also need to tell the printer what to do! Unlike a macro-scale printer, you can't just hook up some wires to a stepper motor or turn a crank on a mill. Instead, the current toolkit is limited to some combination of light, chemical gradients, and "preprogrammed" cascading reactions.

A meta-challenge is that there isn't a clear "best system" for achieving positional chemistry. I've been using a DNA-based 3D printer as an example, but maybe the printer should be built out of proteins, DNA-cast metal, or implosion fabricated materials. Or the 3D-printer approach might be the incorrect first step. An entirely different but potentially exciting approach is to embed molecular motors and switches in a metal-organic framework scaffolding with the whole system acting as a tiny "assembly line," with each step adding or changing the ultimate product. Each approach has its own specialists and advocates. Maybe the most effective approach involves some of all of them. It's a complex systems-engineering question that doesn't yet allow you to abstract things into black boxes in the way that systems engineers like to operate.

Arguably, the biggest meta-challenge is the human one. Everything that I've mentioned so far is primarily in the domain of people who are part of academic chemistry or biology departments. Novelty and papers are strong incentives for them. The answer to the question "This work is excellent β€” how do you think it could be integrated into a bigger system?" is often "No clue. Not my department." As we've discussed, novelty and papers are not bad, but they can be at odds with engineering design. In addition to being fragmented across different academic disciplines, this entire area is heavily stained with what I would call "hype-fallout." During the '90s, people became very excited about the possibilities of "nanotechnology." As a result, the government started pouring money into the area in part by pulling funding from other areas. This funding shift pushed anybody who was doing anything remotely related to processes that occurred on the scale of ~1nm to relabel their work as nanotechnology, diluting the term and blunting progress toward "atomically precise manufacturing" β€” another radioactive term. Combine discipline dilution with overpromises and a healthy dose of crankery and the modern hesitance to take positional chemistry as an engineering problem seriously is entirely reasonable.

Actions

In the near term, a PARPA program could set out to answer the question, "Is it possible to build a system that does positional chemistry?" Or perhaps more aggressively, "Is it possible to build a system that does reconfigurable positional chemistry?" The initial steps would be to fund a number of parallel efforts with the explicit intention of figuring out how to integrate them should they prove promising. Despite the grim picture, the challenges paint there are some reasons to be hopeful. In the past decade, there's been an explosion of tools and techniques to design and fabricate roughly deterministic structures out of biological materials β€” especially DNA β€” and do useful things with them. There are many new ways to simulate and synthesize useful proteins. This work might provide a jumping-off point for positional chemistry.

A non-exclusive list of parallel efforts might look like:

Reasons why PARPA would succeed or fail

A theory which is not refutable by any conceivable event is non-scientific.

β€”Karl Popper, "Science as Falsification"

The ideas I've laid out are not scientific, but it's still important to ask, "How will we know that there is merit to these ideas? What evidence would suggest that they're wrong?" It's tricky because any outcome will doubtless have many causes. Complicating things further is the fact that it's not always clear whether an outcome counts as a success or a failure β€” does dying in the process of killing the minotaur count as success or failure? Grappling with these questions explicitly before the fact is unusual but can hopefully be a bit of a golden thread β€” giving us a sense of when we're moving in the right direction or straying into a trap. I hope that this exercise also enables PARPA to be a useful case study, regardless of its outcome.

Organizational failure scenarios are absurdly contingent, especially when traversing less-trodden paths in obscure mazes. Sometimes it's not a monster that gets the hero but a random falling stalactite. The potentially large effects of small, unanticipated factors is a big reason for this entire piece, and this section in particular; it's important to record hypotheses and how they evolve over time before narrative-building inevitably kicks in around either success or failure. Obviously, there are many unknown unknowns, but if I've done a reasonable job, this section covers most possible scenarios.

Hints of success

PARPA's long-run success looks like being a contingent cause of humanity becoming more awesome. Admittedly, it's hard to get more nebulous, long term, and debatable than that. Instead of a well-defined success condition, it's probably more useful to paint several concrete and shorter-term possibilities that would suggest that we're moving in the direction of success.

Uncomfortably, any one of these success indicators in isolation probably does not point toward broader success. However, it is important to list them in an attempt to minimize either positive or negative hindsight bias. Looking at organizations in hindsight is generally just narrative-building full of both too much "Well, this was actually a success because..." and too much "That didn't really do anything..." So, while any isolated item on this list doesn't count as success, together they're directionally suggestive: The more boxes the organization can check off, the more it will look like a success.

  • Shift ideas from outlandish to mundane . Technological paradigm shifts don't come out of the blue. They are usually preceded by shifting Overton windows around what is impossible, what is feasible, and what is expected. These opinion shifts aren't necessarily causal, so shifting opinion should not be a goal in and of itself but could be a useful leading indicator of doing good work. 279
  • Produce useful ideas or artifacts that other organizations pick up and run with . Creating convincing programs, prototypes, or system-seeds that other organizations pick up and run with is absolutely a leading success indicator. Andy Matuschak put it well: The goal is "developing ideas far enough that they become "obvious," the banal fodder for half a dozen companies in a future YC batch." See " Reflections on 2020 as an independent researcher ." There are traps to be aware of here as well β€” in the same way that an acquired company's product is often quietly shut down, it's a real possibility that other organizations can claim to be pushing ideas or technology forward while quietly smothering or completely mangling it.
  • Create a large impact in a small niche . On the scale of a few years, it's impossible to create unambiguously impactful innovations. Non-digital dissemination is always slower than you expect. However, it may be feasible to create big outcomes among a small group of people β€” perhaps a research domain or a specific set of practitioners.

The last two success indicators are perhaps not leading indicators but "alternative win conditions.'

  • Serve as a jumping-off point for eventually extremely impactful people. History is full of largely forgotten "sceniuses" See " Scenius, or Communal Genius ." that quietly lie in the pasts of an uncanny number of impactful individuals. Creating even a short-lived scenius, like the Rad Lab or Willow Garage, would be a worthy result.
  • In death, serve as an inspiration for similar models . A single organization can't fill all the gaps in the innovation ecosystem, so generating lessons and impetus for other organizations is an actual win (as opposed to a bitter consolation prize). Of course, it's hard to be inspirational when you haven't produced anything of note. Shooting for inspiration without more tangible outcomes is the path of people who have "visionary" on their business cards. So while it's possible for the organization to die prematurely, it still needs other successes.

Longevity and notoriety are not success indicators

The ambiguity between success and failure is compounded by organizational longevity. Any innovation organization that survives long enough will usually end up with one or two wins to its name. I wouldn't call the NSF and NIH shining examples of success, but they have supported many paradigm shifts and Nobel Prizes. I would argue that they achieved these wins through their sheer size and longevity. Perhaps there's a useful efficiency metric like "Nobel Prizes per dollar," but I have no clue what it is. The paired realities that solutions R&D doesn't lend itself to Nobel Prizes and the number of intermediate steps and different actors to get to a clear win makes an efficiency metric hard.

There is something to be said for simply surviving long enough to find the right project or hop on the right S-curve. Innovation organizations can take a long time to hit their stride. Bell Labs didn't start producing the work we laud them for today until more than a decade after the labs were founded. If for some reason they had closed their doors in 1935 (10 years after it was started), they would be barely a blip on the historical radar. Similarly, ARPA's first programs were at the time critical but now forgettable, pursuing questions like "Can we stop a missile strike by exploding a nuclear device in the upper atmosphere?"

The ambiguity around intermediate organizations" impact and the legitimate value of longevity make it easy to tell yourself and the world that you're building up to something great while in fact you will just limp along forever. There are many organizations we can both think of that have done this.

For PARPA, raw survival is not success. One could imagine us surviving for more than a decade, putting out white-papers perhaps backed up by little proof-of-concept experiments without any significant impact. Even if PARPA becomes well known, notoriety doesn't count as success unless it stems from enabling outputs that wouldn't have happened otherwise or serving as a direct model for other people to do that work. At the same time, even if it produces impressive outputs, it's a failure if PARPA winds up effectively indistinguishable from a consulting firm, a government contractor, a startups studio, or other possibilities. I realize this is a high bar.

What would failure look like and why would it happen?

The line between success and failure is more nebulous than we'd like to admit. There's an obvious difference between abject failure and clear success, but a rich spectrum lies between them. This ambiguity is especially prominent for organizations like PARPA that play intermediate roles in the relay race of turning ideas into impactful things in the world. We stand on the shoulders of too many giants to give them all credit.

Precise visions of failure are important because post-hoc success can be woven into a failure narrative and failure can be woven into a success narrative. Some organizations fail to achieve their explicit goals but should go in the success column. Taylor-era PARC 282 and Willow Garage were not particularly long lived (12 and seven years respectively) nor did they live up to the expectations of their creators. However, they ultimately spawned a group of people and projects that had and continue to have a long-term effect. ROS provides the backbone for most modern robotics research, and you're probably reading this on something that can trace its intellectual lineage back to PARC. On the other side of the coin, there is also a class of organizations that have lasted for decades. You could easily weave them into a success narrative, but they somehow smell "off," like something that should have been tossed out long ago. And of course there's everything in between.

Specific failure scenarios

The two clear-cut failure scenarios are a failure to launch and dying before doing anything useful. As discussed above, a more insidious scenario is becoming a "zombie" organization β€” consuming money and mindshare (and perhaps even thinking we're a live player) while ultimately going nowhere.

Below, I will dig into the reasons why those things might happen. Teasing out how one would know that one has fallen into a particular failure mode is more important than enumerating failure modes. I will take a stab at answering "How will we know how we failed?" but you should consider it an open question.

Failure modes fall into two buckets β€” one set of failures apply to DARPA-riffs in general, and the other set applies specifically to PARPA. It's important distinguish between these two categories because I don't want PARPA's failure to condemn the idea of riffing on DARPA as a whole, but at the same time, it's foolish to cling to a failed theory.

Why would riffing on DARPA be a bad idea?

Structure doesn't actually matter

Institutional structure could be much less important to an organization's ability to enable new things than I've argued for . Instead of structure, the factors that determine the activities an organization can do well could depend almost exclusively on its particulars β€” its leaders, its funders, its employees, its time and place. It could also be that structure does matter, but that focusing on DARPA is zooming in on the entirely wrong place on the map.

The current ecosystem has no unfilled niches

One of the core premises behind riffing on DARPA is the assertion that overlapping institutional constraints rule out several classes of creative work , and therefore we need new institutional structures to fill the role that industrial labs once occupied. This could be wrong! It could be that enabling most physically possible technology just takes more people like Elon Musk threading needles with the institutional structures we already have. More broadly, this would mean that existing institutional structures have fewer structural constraints than it seems like they do.

A DARPA-riff is unable to institutionally decouple from papers or profit

A DARPA-riff might inevitably be coupled to other institutions in a way that prevents it from having significantly different constraints. Any DARPA-riff will inevitably need to work with academia for early-stage research and profit-focused companies to diffuse technology. It could be impossible to both work with these other organizations and stand apart from their incentives, slowly but inexorably being pulled to publish or profit.

DARPA-riffs need government funding

The hypothesis that 21st-century riffs on DARPA should be private could be wrong, and it's impossible for a DARPA-riff to succeed without government funding. Perhaps the Department of Defense (and maybe the Department of Homeland Security) is the only place where massive budgets are sufficiently aligned with outputs that don't necessarily generate papers or profits. One could argue that governments are the only institutions that have the time scale (the US government is a relatively young 245) and scope (GDP) to capture the value from long-term, high-uncertainty programs.

Coordinated programs are bunk

It could be that DARPA-style programs are a holdover from the Cold War that don't actually help innovations exist. In our world of shared documents, agile development, and cloud labs, the payoffs for research management could have decreased significantly. Instead of trying to direct research work toward a goal, the correct strategy in all domains might just be, "Give good people money and let them rip!"

Why would PARPA in particular be unsuccessful?

Size

We could fail because a small new institution wouldn't be able to move the needle. We're working off of the hypothesis that it is important for big things to start small, but perhaps a successful DARPA-riff needs to start big. Size could be a failure mode either because to succeed we actually need to start big or because organization fails to grow (for one of many reasons) and fails to hit the critical mass of programs necessary for a DARPA-like portfolio.

Working on the wrong things

PARPA could fail to work on the "right" programs. A causal factor (probably people) could make us consistently bad at designing or picking programs. We could also fall into a trap of working on things that are "easy" instead of "right" β€” an easy program might fit nicely into a budget, be part of a hype wave, or just require convincing fewer people.

This trap is insidious because research has a halting problem β€” you can never be sure that a project won't produce something amazing after dragging on for a long time. This goes for the organization as a whole. However, at some point, even if you have faith in the general DARPA-riff model, it will make sense to kill PARPA after too many failures. It may be impossible to know if it's sheer bad luck or something systemic.

Path dependence

Working on the right things in the wrong order could also lead to failure. If there is fundamental uncertainty about how a program will turn out, you can end up getting a whole bunch of duds in a row. HHTTTT and TTTTHH have the same failure rate, but a string of early successes could buy enough trust that people could roll with a string of failures while a string of early failures could kill the organization before it has a chance to get to the successes.

People

It could just be that I am the wrong person to do this. I bring neither experience managing coordinated research programs nor capital to the table. I could be insufficiently charismatic or outgoing to convince the right people to buy into the project before it has demonstrated success and has its own momentum. I can try to mitigate this by working with other people, but those people need to be convinced as well. It could be that there is a group of people with whom the idea would work, but they end up not being available at the right time. Perhaps they will read this in the future and succeed where I fail. That would be a good outcome.

Shifting technology from impossible to inevitable

We end our exploration of PARPA's idea maze at last.

The maze exists in the first place because constraints on existing institutions have created a gap in the innovation ecosystem. Solutions R&D was once the purview of industrial labs, but no longer. Shifts in both technology and how companies work mean that we can't expect Bell Labs" successor to look anything like Bell Labs. Nor can we count on the two institutions we've defaulted to in the 21st century. Solutions R&D's tense mix of pragmatic application focus and piddling around is too researchy for startups and too engineering-heavy for academia. So, with a respectful hat-tip to Chesterton's Fence, we need something new.

It's impossible to know the true layout of the idea maze before traversing it, but we can make many hypotheses about its twists and turns. While we could start from absolute scratch, it's worthwhile to pay attention to the solutions R&D heroes of yore β€” we can't follow in Bell Labs" footsteps, but it might be possible to follow in DARPA's. There are many junctures that anybody building a DARPA-riff will need to consider: experiments, program managers, time scales, sales channels, missions, and more. Perhaps the thorniest question we'll all need to face is, "How does money work?" Unfortunately, if you draw a box around all the activities in impactful solutions R&D, it's probably not a profitable venture (value creation and value capture are, alas, not always the same). However, there are plenty of strategies that a DARPA-riff can use to get enough money to continue through the maze!

Finally, I want to propose a specific path through the maze β€” PARPA. We can look at PARPA's 283 potential path through the idea maze as a sequence of hypotheses β€” junctures that decrease your risk of failing for each one you successfully pass. Bundled together, PARPA's path through the maze looks like:

1. Create and stress-test unintuitive research programs in a systematic (and therefore repeatable) way.

2. Use that credibility to run a handful of research programs and produce results that wouldn't happen otherwise.

3. Use that credibility to run more research programs and help them "graduate" to effective next steps.

4. Make the entire cycle eventually-autocatalytic by plowing windfalls into an endowment.

Each of the first three steps roughly corresponds to a sequence of organizational "forms" that PARPA will evolve along as it validates hypotheses (or invalidates them and has to figure out new ones).

Any idea maze is fraught with danger β€” many who enter do not survive, and many who survive make it through by the skin of their teeth without real success. There are many ways that PARPA can both succeed and fail; it's important to acknowledge this before setting out so that the journey is not just about its outcome but can help other people traverse the same or similar mazes.

I hope to have convinced you of several points:

  • It's possible to create technology that expands human capability and wonder.
  • Creating this technology requires (among other things!) a set of activities that form a solutions R&D niche in the innovation ecosystem.
  • Built-in constraints prevent modern corporate R&D, academia, and startups from doing a good job at filling the solutions R&D niche.
  • A significant chunk of these constraints has to do with the fact that while profit is important, value capture can hamstring a lot of solutions R&D work.
  • We need to try new organizational and legal models to do good work that is "too researchy for startups and too engineering-heavy for academia."
  • DARPA is a good starting point for creating new organizational and legal models to fill the solutions R&D niche.
  • 21st-century DARPA-riffs need to exist outside of 21st-century government bureaucracies.
  • There are many ways to build a DARPA-riff.
  • There is a set of things every DARPA-riff will need to consider, including PMs, time scales, sales channels, missions, and, perhaps most importantly β€” money.
  • There are many ways that a DARPA-riff can make money, each creating a set of incentives and constraints.
  • Overall, a DARPA-riff that is doing unique work will probably not be profitable, though a portion of it might be.
  • Part of a DARPA-riff's role is to act as a serious context of use for experiments in research management, for example, "It might be possible to develop a discipline around program design."
  • A legal structure comprising a (big-N) Nonprofit and a C-corp will give PARPA the best chance of success and avoiding incentive traps.

If you think these are wrong, show it! Do great solutions R&D within existing institutions! Build a successor to Bell Labs! I like being right, but I would like those things more.

If, however, you think the ideas I've presented are plausible, let's put them into action. There are so many things to be done. You can put these ideas into practice at an existing institution or use them to build a new institution β€” either a DARPA-riff or something entirely different. There are also many concrete ways to help PARPA! Reach out if you or someone you know would make an excellent PM or otherwise want to put legwork into building the organization. Send precise hunches about projects and people who could form the seed of a program. Donate or invest. Or just send this piece to someone who will appreciate it.

Together we can shift technology from impossible to inevitable .

Gratitude

Ideas don't spring out of a single brain, and this piece is no different.

Many excellent people read and helped refine early drafts: Adam Marblestone, Jed McCaleb, Pamela Vagata, Andy Matuschak, Mark McGranaghan, JosΓ© Luis RicΓ³n, Cheryl Reinhardt, Sam Arbesman, Michael Nielsen, Nathan Ihara, Martin Permin, Luke Constable, Arnaud Schenk.

We stand on the shoulders of too many giants to give them all credit, but to list a few who helped me grope through the idea maze: Marissa Weichman, Ilan Gur, Semon Rezchikov, Tim Hwang, Jeff Graham, Arati Prabhakar, Patrick Collison, Malcolm Handley, Olivia Wang, Noah Tye, Rebecca Li, Steven Glinert, Keegan McNamara, Michael Filler, Matt Clifford, Adrienne Little, Peter van Hardenberg, Josh Tobin, Cameron Kelly, Evan Miyazono, Jeff Lipton, Lee Ricketson, Adit Swarup, Alexey Guzey, Sebastian Winther, Luke Durant, Rachel Zucker, and Victoria Chen.

The styling and interface of this website is mostly derived from Andy Matuschak and Michael Nielsen, "How can we develop transformative tools for thought?", https://numinous.productions/ttft , San Francisco (2019).

This work was graciously sponsored by the Astera Institute .

If you want to support PARPA with either your time or money, please reach out !

Corrections

6 May 2021 : An earlier version indicated that Dynamicland had shut down. This is not true! Dynamicland is still going strong, just quiet.


  1. "Long-term" roughly translates to "more than five years." ↩

  2. My unsubstantiated personal opinion is that analyses on high-level metrics like total factor productivity contribute to this unhelpful lumping. ↩

  3. Yes, it's a much less catchy question. And in this particular case the book does delve into the institutional constraints; many people do not. ↩

  4. Invoking Cunningham's Law, I will say this very aggressively in the hopes that I am wrong. ↩

  5. This idea might be a fallacy. Arguably, there is no platonic "ultimate stage" of a technology, and whatever a technology evolves into is indelibly touched by the different specialized forms it needed to pass through. ↩

  6. There are a number of just-so stories I could tell about why these university spinoffs are different from the list of successes. Most of those on the list were not deeply new technologies, their founders were brilliant and plotted the exact path to success; it's easier to go into new niches with software and chips; they got lucky; I'm a moron; etc. However, the empirical evidence is that so many niche-seeking startups built around new (genuinely cool) technologies fail to help that technology realize its potential. ↩

  7. I'm not trying to disparage VC and startups. There are many amazing things that have come out of the system. What I am asserting is the incorrectness of the idea that "if it wasn't a viable startup it would never have been able to be amazing for the world in the long run" ↩

  8. Though this time period is probably longer than it would have been because it was interrupted by a world war. ↩

  9. I will touch on academia's constraints lightly here β€” only enough to draw the contrast to industrial labs. More on this later! ↩

  10. It's worth spending more time thinking about the "dimensions" of the Valley of Death, because it's not as much a matter of number of people as the "ramp" language here might imply. ↩

  11. Condition 3 was originally "1+2 are insufficient if the technology the lab works on isn't tied into the company's core business." However, this isn't quite right. There are situations where technology work on the core product can have nothing to do with existential risks to the business (for example, Salesforce). Similarly, there are situations where technology work has little to do with the core product but addresses an existential threat (for example, flashy research at Bell Labs keeping regulators from breaking up the monopoly). ↩

  12. Some people use the term "money fountain." It's evocative but I think this sounds a bit too magical. Money factories are mystical enough. ↩

  13. Figuring out how to develop technology faster is so impactful because it breaks this initial assumption and weakens the dependence on a money factory. At the same time, technology R&D and diffusion timescales seem weirdly robust, so the burden of proof is on anyone who claims to have sped up the process. ↩

  14. There is, of course, an entire literature about projects like this going drastically over budget and timeline. ↩

  15. Although better program design could help! ↩

  16. It would be fascinating if someone did a study on the full two-by-two: situations where expectations of success helped a project and hurt that project, and where expectations of failure did the same. ↩

  17. I suspect these arguments apply to innovation organizations in general, but I want to narrow the scope here a bit just to research organizations. ↩

  18. Or at least be perceived to be addressing existential threats β€” there are many organizations that successfully maintain funding based purely on great marketing. It's worth paying attention to why this marketing works, but I'm going to otherwise ignore it because I am bad at pulling off false pretenses and would prefer if the world had fewer of them. ↩

  19. This is very true of 1960s ARPA, but less so of DARPA. Over time, Congress has exerted more direct oversight over DARPA programs. That being said, there's still less overhead than there is in other government research. ↩

  20. It's unclear whether they should even be called labs! ↩

  21. Lockheed Martin is supposedly working on a portable fusion reactor. ↩

  22. Before you write me an angry email, I am not saying that all teams at all industrial labs are now C players, but it is undeniable that most people <em>on the academic track</em> don't view industrial labs as first-class alternatives to universities. ↩

  23. At this point, OpenAI vaguely resembles the Bell Labs equivalent for Microsoft. ↩

  24. Yes, Google and Facebook are not technically monopolies in the full AT&T or Standard Oil sense, but the flavor of their profit margins and sizes are similar. ↩

  25. Maybe it's a Seattle thing? ↩

  26. I'm not going to dig into the philosophy of what makes something good. I am an unabashed explorationist, but I'm pretty sure you could make a utilitarian argument as well. ↩

  27. Positive in the sense of "positivist," not in the sense of "Yeah! Science!" ↩

  28. "The Cell! DNA!" You may shout. It's hard to argue that we have benefited from manipulating DNA as much as we did from manipulating electrons. Biology certainly has that <em>potential</em>, but so did nuclear physics ... ↩

  29. Which, like the DOE itself, were originally created for the sole purpose of smoothly transitioning nuclear weapons from proof of concept to manufactured product! ↩

  30. Broadly including institutions in their ecosystems, like venture capital, incubators, and national research centers. ↩

  31. There are many others! ↩

  32. In fact, it would be accurate to draw an arrow from the bottom of engineering design to the bottom of scientific inquiry and do the same from the top of scientific inquiry to the top of engineering design, creating an ouroboros, the mythical snake eating its own tail. ↩

  33. This can of course happen outside of academia! But in academia it can go on forever without running into the cold hard wall that is reality. ↩

  34. And through self-reinforcing cultural evolution. ↩

  35. See especially: any graduate work that involves culturing cells or working with equipment that is more than 30 years old. ↩

  36. "But they were published and now have many citations!" you say. Yes, after years of struggling to publish and get funding. There is a heavy survivorship bias here, because there's rarely anything to point to in situations where something wasn't published. ↩

  37. Despite the fact that there is an increasingly wide gap between the number of graduate students training for PhDs and the number of academic positions for them to fill! ↩

  38. There will always be exceptions! ↩

  39. Basically the entire world is a monetized economy as of the early 21st century. There is a whole other rabbit hole about the goodness or badness of that fact, but I'm going to avoid that discussion and just treat a monetized economy as a given. ↩

  40. This is not a new phenomenon. Newton spent the last decades of his life working at the Royal Mint instead of doing physics. ↩

  41. Shannon made a killing on the stock market, but as far as anybody knows, he didn't use information theory to do it. ↩

  42. To complicate things, many small contracting firms only work for the US government, so they may be part of the government for all intents and purposes. ↩

  43. My past self included. ↩

  44. \<Sidenote> See<a href="https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/NBK221876/"> Scientific Knowledge as a Global Public Good - Contributions to Innovation and the Economy</a>. ↩

  45. I am not a lawyer, this is not legal advice. ↩

  46. The Wright Brothers famously spent a lot of time litigating patents. ↩

  47. Charles Goodyear - one of the inventors of vulcanized rubber lost a series of court cases and made little money from his invention. ↩

  48. If the technology is modular enough that it can easily be sold and incorporated into many other products, it's still just a product. ↩

  49. Yes, you can probably come up with an obscure scenario where studying these things (or anything) is valuable. My point is that justifying research based on the value it creates at all is an incomplete stance. ↩

  50. Show that I'm wrong please! ↩

  51. This is two orders of magnitude larger than US population growth. ↩

  52. It was (and still is) a giant cost and pain. ↩

  53. The equivalent of suing someone who isn't paying the licensing fees on a patent. ↩

  54. Note that this isn't a good or a bad thing β€” while the default reaction at least in Silicon Valley circles is that it is. ↩

  55. Although, cognitive-dissonance-introducingly, there are nonprofits that make a large profit in everything but the legal sense, and for-profits that don't seek to maximize profits at all. ↩

  56. Less-used tax designations vary both over space and time, like S-corps or benefit corps. For example, as of late 2020, benefit corporations are authorized in 35 out of 50 US states. They exist in some states but not in other states, and are legislated into existence and sometimes out of existence. ↩

  57. That is, particle physics before subatomic particles β€” now it's just a mess all the way down. ↩

  58. The property that you don't actually know where the line is until you cross it is true in law more broadly. Some legal scholars in common-law countries like the US consider it a good thing when laws are challenged, because more rulings give a better sense of where the line is. ↩

  59. Admittedly, the number of organizations constrained out of existence by people's unwillingness to play with legal structures might be zero. But it also might be huge. Counterfactuals are hard! ↩

  60. One could argue how much of this is just talk, but I default to trust, and it helps argue my point. ↩

  61. Former PMs are still (understandably) hesitant to talk about could-have-been program ideas. ↩

  62. And even then, it depends on which government you are part of. ↩

  63. I want to caveat that the moon landings could not have been accomplished without government funding in the 1960s. Whether something requires government-level funding is not an inherent property of that thing but instead depends on the nature of the work at the time, the relative wealth of the society, and the concentration of that wealth. In the "60s, NASA needed to do a ton of new things, the US was not as wealthy as it is now, and that wealth was less concentrated (fewer billionaires). ↩

  64. I like to think of this like how polynomial approximations are valid in a local area around an equilibrium. ↩

  65. There are few things more fun to talk about than how messed up your old company was. ↩

  66. These people should not visit climbing gyms. ↩

  67. There's not a great word for these people. "End users" sounds incredibly clinical, and alternatives like "consumers" invoke large numbers of unsophisticated people. ↩

  68. Who/which member of an organization is actually spending the money? Who do you need to convince that it's a good idea? How does the customer know it works? What does the contract look like? Do you need to go through a third party? These are of course questions for any product (and invite innovation!), but more established types of products have more standard answers. ↩

  69. Obviously, there is much more haggling involved, but it is a much more straightforward conversation for both sides. ↩

  70. This word also feels insufficient, but is the commonly used word for "getting technology to end users." I'm going to be a bit sloppy and jump between "selling" and "diffusing." ↩

  71. At least at the program level. ↩

  72. To paint the counterfactual of explicitly making sure experiments have no negative consequences: One could imagine that after a failed seedling experiment a PM could implicitly or explicitly need to "redeem" themselves by going above and beyond. Similarly, the organizational attitude toward a performer who ran a failed experiment might implicitly shift towards "Well they're good people but a bit incompetent." ↩

  73. As opposed to something like flossing, where people are like, "Yeah, I really should be doing that ... later." ↩

  74. This is an example of the more general principle that optimizing individual components of a system is often at odds with the system itself. ↩

  75. The term "relationships" is usually a suitcase word, so I'm going to strive to be as specific as possible here. ↩

  76. Ack! So many suitcase words! ↩

  77. It's jumping ahead a bit, but this is a key reason why it's important to a replicable institutional model. ↩

  78. "I'm busy writing my thesis. Here's my lab computer β€” it has everything on it. Good luck!" ↩

  79. People absolutely run out of patience, even if you set expectations up front. Based on popular sentiment, if Blue Origin had any funders besides Jeff Bezos, they would have lost funding despite the fact that they literally have tortoises on their coat of arms. ↩

  80. Peter van Hardenberg poetically names this an organization's "Reaper function." ↩

  81. Though, of course, circumstances could have changed to make this no longer true. ↩

  82. "Friendly investment" is what I would call investment from nonprofessional investors that is some superposition of philanthropy and investment. That is, unlike professional investors, who implicitly or explicitly want to see a certain level of growth on a clear timeline, friendly investment is more like an option β€” if the asset becomes worth something, awesome! If not, disappointing but πŸ€·β€β™‚οΈ. Of course, friendly investment always runs the risk of becoming unfriendly at any time β€” the classic example is entrepreneurs who get their first startup money from friends and family who have no experience with startup investing. A lot of angel investing could be considered friendly investing. ↩

  83. Of course, individuals within organizations also have their own agendas. ↩

  84. I only took the top 20 companies because company valuation roughly follows a power law, so the bottom 200 will probably add up to be much less than the top 20. ↩

  85. There are obvious exceptions for extremely expensive or rare equipment ↩

  86. As suitcase-y as this term can be. ↩

  87. It's worth noting that of these, only the Santa Fe Institute does not have a large endowment. ↩

  88. "When a measure becomes a target, it ceases to be a good measure." ↩

  89. Charities can't lock in commitments the way for-profit funds can. ↩

  90. "Small donors" here means that each individual donor provides less than 2% of total funding. ↩

  91. Foundations are legally required to disburse at least 5% of their assets toward their charitable missions every year. ↩

  92. Legally, foundations aren't allowed to make "excessively risky investments." ↩

  93. Are you starting to see why all these legal shenanigans matter? ↩

  94. Yes, I'm using an absurd number of quotation marks β€” this is yet another artifact of the fact that there are no first principles for legal structures! All of these words are legal designations, but it's nebulous which things fall in and out of them. ↩

  95. Of course, members of a consortium are not automatically "bought in" to everything that comes out of it. ↩

  96. Spoiler alert: Speculatively, this is a good idea! ↩

  97. Beyond reporting requirements, which, as we'll see, are thick strings indeed. ↩

  98. Although, in early-21st-century America, there is a lot of rhetoric around directly getting a return for taxpayers as though the government is an investment fund. ↩

  99. Of course, the government is composed of individuals who all have their own agendas and geographies. ↩

  100. This is why unrestricted money is like gold for professors. ↩

  101. Except for it's majority-internalized research, DeepMind is basically an AI-focused DARPA-riff. ↩

  102. DeepMind is technically an Alphabet subsidiary with its own leadership, budgets, etc. ↩

  103. Google Brain's timeline corroborates this: It started as a small project within Google X in 2011 and only became a full organization around 2013. ↩

  104. "The best way to predict the future is to invent it." β€”Alan Kay ↩

  105. Contra an "impossible" situation where the number came out bigger than the market capitalization of Amazon, for example. ↩

  106. Yes, "better" is a vague word. In the context of program design, it means some combination of faster, cheaper, more successfully, enabling programs that wouldn't exist otherwise, and generating more knowledge in both successes and failures. ↩

  107. Many disciplines that are meant to supplement practice suffer the same fate! ↩

  108. I have tried to track them down to ask them, but they all seem to be unreachable or dead. If you know any of them, please put us in touch! ↩

  109. See: alchemy, astrology, humor-based medicine. ↩

  110. In the Popperian sense. ↩

  111. Simulations, specifically simulations of nuclear detonations, were among the first applications of digital computers. ↩

  112. And ideally non-researchers! See: Foldit below. ↩

  113. I would argue that this is the case despite recent (2021) events. ↩

  114. There are of course exceptions, and those people go work in finance. ↩

  115. Which does happen sometimes! ↩

  116. I want to acknowledge up-front that "vision" and "visionary" have become grossly overloaded suitcase words. Unfortunately, it is also the correct word for what I'm talking about. I tried "crisp picture" and "shared goal," but they just don't work. It's also hard to define in a non-circular manner from the content of this note. Hopefully this excessive note serves to sufficiently discriminate precise visions from the casual use of the word! ↩

  117. "What are you working on?" is an intriguing question. What counts as a legitimate answer to it is slippery. There are answers that are clearly legitimate, like "We're working on making webpage load times faster!" Unfortunately, "We're working on a new institutional structure" is generally illegitimate. Perhaps it comes down to whether the questioner can imagine the sorts of day-to-day activities an answer would entail? ↩

  118. There are, of course, many examples of startups drastically shifting what they're working on. At any point in time, though, good startups tend to know exactly what they're working on. ↩

  119. This isn't to say all software engineers or data scientists are fungible! It is to say that the startup's ability to take even one step forward doesn't hinge on hiring the best software engineer in the world. ↩

  120. There are plenty of people who have no idea what they're talking about with great ideas that would change the world "if only they could find someone to implement them." ↩

  121. The counterexamples that immediately popped into your head are the result of saliency bias. It's easy to recall people who openly want to work on things beyond their reach, but obviously hard to recall the people who never talk about them. ↩

  122. I think credentialism is bad and that most people can retrain to do most things eventually if they try hard. However, success on a technically hard non-software research project starting from scratch without guidance seems ... unlikely. ↩

  123. The tension between expertise and ambition strikes again! ↩

  124. See question 4 of the Heilmeier Catechism: "Who cares? If you are successful, what difference will it make?" ↩

  125. I prefer the imagery invoked by "budding off" companies instead of spinning out, but the convention is strong with this one. ↩

  126. Though they rarely do in practice. ↩

  127. 1974 Bell Labs and 2020 DARPA have uncannily similar budgets ($3.6B and $2.8B in 2020 dollars) β€” there is not clear causal linkage, but it is suggestive. ↩

  128. If every company whose core business depends on technology that can be traced back to DARPA gave some tiny percent of their revenue to DARPA, it would fund DARPA many times over. (And in a way they do, via taxes in the US.) ↩

  129. As with any metric, it will be imperfect. It's not actually possible to convert between four years of service and $200K. Both are essential and not interchangeable. ↩

  130. While a DARPA-riff will need at least seven programs to demonstrate viability, we could design the remaining programs once we've moved to Form 2. ↩

  131. I've received drastically different response rates sending emails with the slightly different wording "potential privately funded research program..." and just "potential research program..." ↩

  132. Speculatively, it might be possible to improve on the Heilmeier Catechism with something more quantized β€” similar to Donald Braben's BRAVERI scale. ↩

  133. You also need some amount of slack for these benefits to kick in. If everybody is spending 110% of their time focused on only their own programs, any non-program-related interaction is mentally expensive. ↩

  134. Note that I'm <em>not</em> saying this is necessarily the right thing to build, but it does seem promising. ↩

  135. This distinction between leading indicator and goal in and of itself is of course the root of Goodhart's Law. We can hopefully sidestep the trap of leading indicators becoming goals by having too many indicators to pursue all of them without just pursuing the thing they indicate! ↩

  136. While Xerox PARC technically still exists, after a leadership change in 1983, it arguably morphed into a different organization. ↩

  137. The P is for "private," but you can also imagine that it stands for "phenomenal" or "prodigious" if you want. ↩

License

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License. This means you’re free to copy, share, and build on the work, provided you attribute it appropriately. Please click on the following license link for details: Creative
        Commons License